[EM] 03/30/02 - Re: How to vote in Approval:
Dave Ketchum
davek at clarityconnect.com
Tue Apr 2 11:06:35 PST 2002
On Mon, 1 Apr 2002 12:42:03 -0800 (PST) Forest Simmons wrote:
> On Sun, 31 Mar 2002, Adam Tarr wrote:
>
>
>>Dave wrote:
>>
>>
>>>I have nothing nice to say about Approval, noting that no one seems able
>>>to give me useful guidelines as to how well I should have to like a
>>>candidate to say "approve".
>>>
>>Rob LeGrand came up with a decent strategy that makes a lot of
>>sense. Approve every candidate you like more than the front runner, and
>>approve the front runner if you like him/her more than the second-place
>>candidate. This requires knowing who's top two in the polls, but this is a
>>pretty good bet in a large election.
>>
>
> Here's another approach that is near optimal in practice:
>
> (1) rank the candidates as you would for your favorite Condorcet method.
> (2) convert the ranks to Borda scores by subtracting from the number of
> candidates.
> (3) adjust the numbers so that they better reflect your relative
> intensities of preference or "utilities" for the candidates. Call these
> numbers "ratings."
> (4) assign subjective probabilities of winning for each candidate.
> (5) multiply the ratings by the respective probabilities and add the
> results to get what we will call the expected winner rating (EWR).
> (6) approve all of the candidates that you have rated above this EWR.
>
> In the case of zero information all of the probabilities would be equal,
> so you would be approving by the "above mean utility strategy" which is
> often advocated as near optimal for the zero-info case. In other words,
> this strategy is a straight-forward extension of the above mean utility
> strategy.
With my voter hat on, these strange sentences cannot be worth trying to
decipher.
With my student hat on, prospects do not look much better.
>
> <snip>
>
>>Approval certainly has its places. If I had to advocate wide-scale single
>>winner voting reform to a large group that was not familiar with it, my
>>inclination is to advocate approval voting. It's simple and it's an
>>obvious improvement over plurality. But if I'm trying to turn around an
>>IRV advocate, I would definitely jump straight to advocating Condorcet
>>voting. Once someone has accepted the concept of ranked ballots, they have
>>a certain intuitive appeal that's hard to give up. It's hard to convince
>>someone who's bought into IRV that you get better results with plain old
>>unranked approval ballots. But a few simple examples will convince all but
>>the most hardheaded IRV advocate that Condorcet is superior.
>>
>
> Yes, if they are willing to fill out the IRV ballots, show them what those
> ballots can do, given half a chance.
I miss understanding how filling out Condorcet ballots, or even the
identical IRV ballots (unless IRV inspires an attempt at strategy), is so
complicated. Simply indicate my strongest preferences until I get down to
not worth bothering with - what could be simpler?
It is the vote counting and calculating that contains any complexity.
>
> Better yet, show them the advantages of CR ballots where you don't have to
> pretend that all of your preferences are of equal intensity.
>
> Most people don't have the patience to rank two dozen candidates. Giving
> each a grade of A,B,C,D,F or (default) E, is easier.
But, in IRV or Condorcet, I quit as soon as I have said all I care to say.
Assigning grades is a complication that is not worth the pain.
>
> [The reason I believe the default grade should be E, is that F should be
> reserved for someone that you are sure about being no good. But beware,
> this convention might backfire if you allow election of someone with a
> majority of below D grades.]
>
>
> Forest
--
davek at clarityconnect.com http://www.clarityconnect.com/webpages3/davek
Dave Ketchum 108 Halstead Ave, Owego, NY 13827-1708 607-687-5026
Do to no one what you would not want done to you.
If you want peace, work for justice.
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list