[EM] Detailed stats for the ordinal methods
Chris Benham
cbenhamau at yahoo.com.au
Sat May 11 20:35:04 PDT 2024
>
> Strategic nomination can indeed be a problem and should be
> investigated more closely. James-Green Armytage showed that IRV has
> greater exit incentive than the Condorcet-IRV methods do, for instance.
Kristofer,
Can you please point me to this?
Chris
On 12/05/2024 6:18 am, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:
> On 2024-05-09 23:56, Closed Limelike Curves wrote:
>> Hi Kristofer! Thanks for this :)
>>
>> I do want to ask though, do you think the rate of manipulable
>> elections is a good measure of the "general strategy resistance" of
>> an electoral method? The resistant set certainly seems to reduce that
>> rate, but for all I know that 7.5% is all turkey-elections.
>
> The narrow sense of turkey elections - exploiting nonmonotonicity to
> do pushover - must, for ordinal methods, belong to the "Other"
> strategy category. Not every Other strategy need to be pushover, but
> pushover must be an Other strategy. Let's consider Resistant,Borda again:
>
>>> Ties: 0.001 (5)
>>> Of the non-ties:
>>>
>>> Burial, no compromise: 123 0.0246246
>>> Compromise, no burial: 72 0.0144144
>>> Burial and compromise: 147 0.0294294
>>> Two-sided: 48 0.00960961
>>> Other coalition strats: 1 0.0002002
>>> ================================================
>>> Manipulable elections: 391 0.0782783
>
> There's only one out of 4995 elections with "other" strats. So
> pushover manipulability is very low. (I've designed resistant set
> methods that seem to have no pushover at all, even though they fail
> monotonicity. I haven't been able to prove why certain resistant set
> constructions make pushover impossible, though.)
>
> I can think of two ways to formalize the broader category of
> turkey-raising as mentioned on Electowiki. They would be:
> - Supporters of candidate A encourage a candidate C to enter, so
> that C>B>A voters express their honest opinion; but that makes A win
> instead.
> - By making C appear to have more support than he actually does,
> supporters of candidate A trick strategic B>C>A voters to compromise
> for C. As a result, the winner changes from B to A.
>
> Neither effect is captured in my simulations: the first would be a
> form of strategic nomination, and the second is a strategic play under
> imperfect information. As the number of candidates doesn't change, and
> the simulation involves a fully honest election followed by
> full-information strategy, it doesn't capture either.
>
> Strategic nomination can indeed be a problem and should be
> investigated more closely. James-Green Armytage showed that IRV has
> greater exit incentive than the Condorcet-IRV methods do, for
> instance. I haven't written code to do this, and thus my stats don't
> provide any information about strategic nomination.
>
> Taking the second effect into account would be very difficult, as
> we're then moving into a repeated game of imperfect information. But,
> as a heuristic, if the voters know that the method has low (ordinary)
> manipulability, then it would probably be harder to get them to engage
> in a self-destructive strategy as well, since it would be harder to
> get them to engage in strategy in general.
>
> And a final caveat: if you combine a strategy resistant method with
> primaries or other parts, the composition could have turkey
> strategies. I imagine that the likelihood of this happening depends on
> the strategic nomination incentives for the method: so you could see
> it with IRV but it would be less likely with Smith-IRV.
>
> -km
> ----
> Election-Methods mailing list - see https://electorama.com/em for list
> info
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list