[EM] Strategy-free criterion
Chris Benham
cbenhamau at yahoo.com.au
Mon Jun 3 02:30:42 PDT 2024
Kevin,
> MD basically says that if there are two frontrunners and everyone truncates their
> less liked frontrunner, then the worse frontrunner won't win. If this property
> doesn't hold, it means the majority has done something to stop the method from
> "seeing" their majority, which is surely that they ranked other candidates above
> the preferred frontrunner.
Instead of "above the preferred frontrunner" don't you mean *below the
less-liked frontrunner*?
The classic example used by people who like Winning Votes and Approval
to flout those method's compliance with MD (versus the MD failures of
Margins and IRV):
49 A (sincere might be A>B)
24 B (sincere might be B>C)
27 C>B (sincere)
A>C 49-27 (=23) C>B 27-24 (=3) B>A 51-49 (=2)
By Margins A's defeat is the weakest and MinMax (and methods that are
equivalent to it with only 3 candidates, such as Ranked Pairs and
Schulze) using margins elects A.
But Minimal Defense says "not A" because more than half the voters voted
B above A and A not above equal-bottom. MD has no problem with the 27
C>B voters who ranked a candidate above their preferred (presumably
perceived) "frontrunner."
What you wrote seems to better apply to another criterion about voters
"defending the (presumed) sincere CW", Steve Eppley's "Non-Drastic
Defense" that says that if more than half the voters rank X above Y and
X no lower than equal-top then Y can't win.
I think this was his example:
46 A>C (sincere is A>B)
17 B>A (sincere)
17 B>C (sincere)
20 C=B (sincere is C>B)
A>C 63-37 (=26) C>B 46-34 (=12) B>A 54-46 (=8)
More than half the voters have voted B above A and B no lower than
equal-top and so NDD says that A can't win, but Margins elects A.
Winning Votes meets NDD and elects B.
Chris B.
On 2/06/2024 7:23 am, Kevin Venzke wrote:
> Hi all,
>
> When I test for SFC compliance the rule on cast votes is that if there is no
> majority over A, and A has a majority over B, then B can't win.
>
> This is kind of a flip side of MD / SDSC because, if you were forced to explain MD
> in terms of a graph of majority-strength defeats, it would say that if A has a
> majority over B and B doesn't have a majority over anyone, then B can't win.
>
> MD basically says that if there are two frontrunners and everyone truncates their
> less liked frontrunner, then the worse frontrunner won't win. If this property
> doesn't hold, it means the majority has done something to stop the method from
> "seeing" their majority, which is surely that they ranked other candidates above
> the preferred frontrunner. So MD is mostly about compromise incentive.
>
> SFC is probably going to be about truncation. When a method fails it, most likely
> it's because the majority gave the election away to a less liked compromise choice.
> For example:
>
> 20 C>A>B
> 35 A>B
> 5 B
> 40 D
>
> Here B is the implicit approval winner, but by SFC B should not win, because it
> means it was not safe for the A voters to rank B.
>
> I would not like to see SFC as totally obsolete, since it was one of the motivating
> criteria (along with MD and weak FBC) for my methods MDDA and MAMPO :)
>
> Kevin
> votingmethods.net
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list