[EM] Mono-switch-Plump criterion compliance claims corrected
C.Benham
cbenham at adam.com.au
Mon Oct 24 04:58:59 PDT 2016
The Mono-switch-plump criterion is much stronger than I previously
thought, and is probably simply incompatible with the
Condorcet criterion.
I used to think that its met by two of my favourite Condorcet methods,
Margins-Sorted Losing Votes (erw) Elimination (equivalent in the 3
candidate case
to the "MMLV(erw)M" I discuss in the May 2014 post) and Approval Sorted
Margins. Consider this election under MSLVerwE :
40: A
29: C>A
03: B
28: B>C
A>B 69-31, B>C 31-29, C>A 57-40. LV(erw) scores: A40 > B31 >
C29. No adjacent pair is out-of-order pairwise, so MSLV(erw)E elects A.
But if we switch the 3 B plumping ballots to A then C becomes the
Condorcet winner (C>B 29-28, C>A 57-43).
43: A
29: C>A
28: B>C
And now this election under Approval Sorted Margins:
30: C
04: C>A
33: A>B
32: B
A>B 37-32, B>C 64-34, C>A 34-33. (Implicit) Approval scores: B64
> A37 > C34. The adjacent pair with the smallest (absolute margin)
difference
in their scores (A > C) is pairwise out of order so we flip that to give
B > C > A. Now neither adjacent pair is pairwise out-of-order, so the
order is
final and so Margins Sorted Approval elects B.
But if we switch two of the 32 B plumping ballots to A then A becomes
the Condorcet winner (A>B 39-34, A>C 35-34).
30: C
04: C>A
33: A>B
02: A
30: B
I doubt that IBIFA meets the criterion.
But I remain sure that it's met by Bucklin (and similar methods like MTA
and MCA and QLTD).
Chris Benham
On 11 May 2014 Chris Benham posted to EM:
>
>> Mono-switch-plump:
>>
>> *The probability of candidate X winning must not be reduced if one or
>> more ballots that
>> plump for any not-X are replaced by an equal number of ballots that
>> plump for X.*
>
> Previously I showed that this is failed by the following methods:
>
> Schulze (aka Beatpath), Ranked Pairs, River, MinMax (all equivalent
> with 3 candidates) if they use Winning Votes to weigh pairwise defeats.
>
> IRV and the Condorcet methods based on IRV (such as Benham and Woodall)
>
> Total Approval Chain Climbing.
>
> I claim that it is met by Margins, any positional method, IBIFA,
> Bucklin and Bucklin-like methods like Median Ratings and MCA and MTA.
>
> And also it is met by MMLV(erw)M. To support that claim I'll just
> talk about the Margins Sort version with 3 candidates.
>
> Plumping ballots for any X always contribute to X's score and
> switching plumping ballots to X might get rid of one of X's pairwise
> defeats.
>
> If X has no pairwise defeats then that will always be still the case
> after switching some plumping ballots to X and so X will still win. X
> can't
> be a winner with all pairwise defeats so we are only concerned about
> the case when X has just one (and so will the other 2 candidates).
>
> Say we designate the candidate with the highest score 1, the
> second-highest 2 and and the lowest 3. The algorithm in this
> 3-candidate cycle
> situation elects 1 unless 2 both pairwise beats 1 and has a score
> that is closer to 1's than to 3's.
>
> If winning candidate X is in position 2 then the effect of plumping
> ballots being switched from 1 to 2 will be to just make 2 still
> closer to 1,
> and the effect of plumping ballots being switched from 3 to 2 will
> have the same effect (and make 3 further away).
>
> If winning candidate X is 1 and pairwise beats 2 and loses to 3,
> then the only hope of making 1 lose is to switch some plumping ballots
> from
> 2 to 1 sufficient for 2 and 3 to change places but that won't work
> because then 2 and 3 will be adjacent candidates that are out of pairwise
> order and will be much closer together score-wise than the other such
> pair and they'll be switched back to give the final order 1>2>3.
>
> And if X is 1 and losing to 2 then it means that 1's distance
> (scorewise) from 2 is such that 2 and 3 are switched in the order, and
> switching
> any plumping ballots to 1 will only increase that distance.
>
> I hope that (almost confused) waffle is not too confusing or opaque.
>
> Chris Benham
>
>
>
>
>
> Mono-switch-plump:
>
> *The probability of candidate X winning must not be reduced if one or
> more ballots that
> plump for any not-X are replaced by an equal number of ballots that
> plump for X.*
>
> Mono-raise is the traditional monotonicity criterion, but I don't see
> why anyone would
> see failure of Mono-switch-plump as less embarrassing than failing
> Mono-raise.
>
>
> 25 A>B
> 26 B>C
> 23 C>A
> 22 C
> 04 A
>
> B>C 51-45 C>A 71-29 A>B 52-26
>
> Top Preferences: C45 > A29 > B26
>
> When there are three candidates the MinMax , Beatpath (aka Schulze),
> Ranked Pairs and River algorithms
> are all equivalent. When they use Winning Votes as the measure of
> defeat strength they all elect C.
>
> IRV (aka the Alternative Vote) and Benham (and Woodall) also elect
> C. But if we replace the 4A ballots
> with 4C ballots the winner with all these methods changes from C to B.
>
> 25 A>B
> 26 B>C
> 23 C>A
> 26 C
>
> B>C 51-49 C>A 71-29 A>B 48-26
>
> Top Preferences: C45 > B26 > A25
>
> Total Approval Chain Climbing also fails.
>
> 25 A>B
> 06 A>C
> 32 B>C
> 27 C>A
> 08 C
> 02 B
>
> C>A>B>C, Approvals C73 > B59 > A58
>
> TACC elects C, but if the 2B ballots are changed to 2C, then the
> winner changes to A.
>
> 25 A>B
> 06 A>C
> 32 B>C
> 27 C>A
> 10 C
>
> C>A>B>C, Approvals C75 > A58 > B57
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20161024/85697c01/attachment.htm>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list