[EM] Critique of FairVote's "approval voting" report
Jameson Quinn
jameson.quinn at gmail.com
Sat Oct 15 20:48:18 PDT 2011
The critique now has a number of comments in the margin, from a number of
people, including responses from Rob Richie (probably the original author of
the report). At the bottom, I've added my critique of the pervasive error
Fairvote (Richie?) makes. Here is a copy of my critique:
Strategy in Approval: the real story
In order to understand what the effect of “strategic” approval voting is, we
must first have some definition of “honest” approval voting to compare it
against. Various definitions are possible:
1.
Approve any candidate who’s better than the average serious candidate.
-
This is close to perfect strategy, so while it’s a fair definition of
“honest”, we can’t really use this as a basis for comparing how
much of an
advantage strategy gives. To do so could be criticized as biased
in favor of
approval.
2.
Bullet vote. That is, approve only a single candidate.
-
This is apparently Fairvote’s (mistaken) idea of a strategy, so I
guess we can’t use this as a basis for comparison either.
3.
Anti-bullet vote. That is, approve all but a single candidate.
-
This is a stupid strategy, and one which most people, who tend to be
partisan and tribal, would not naturally tend to use. I only mention it
because it’s the definition of “honest” used by Tideman. We will
not use it
here.
4.
Set your approval threshold arbitrarily, somewhere in between your
favorite and least-favorite candidate, and approve everyone above the
threshold.
-
Obviously, people will be more likely to approve of a candidate the
more they like that candidate. With enough voters, the law of
averages will
even out the randomness of the arbitrary decisions, and so the
system will
become roughly equivalent to range voting. (Technically speaking, it
will be range voting, with the true range vote passed through some
monotonically increasing, probably roughly integral-sign-shaped,
probability
function; and with some slight random noise proportional to the
square root
of the number of voters, around 0.1% for a million voters).
Since definitions 1 and 2 could be called biased in favor of approval
voting, and definition 3 is just stupid, we’ll use definition 4 for the rest
of this analysis.
Note that under definition 4, the honest approval winner is just the
honest range winner. That has been shown to be the system which comes
closest to electing the true utility winner for the voters - the winner who
makes the average voter happiest. So this is an excellent result for honest
approval.
So, what about strategy? Is it true, as Fairvote claims, that “strategic
voters will always earn a significant advantage over less informed voters”?
Well, that depends what you mean by “strategy”.
Let’s start by trying Fairvote’s definition:
“...[V]oters who vote tactically by casting a single vote for their
favorite candidate will gain an advantage over those voters who indicate
support for more than one candidate....”
This is totally false. Such voters will only gain an advantage if their
favorite candidate wins. On the other hand, they will be hurting themselves
if they happen to have favored the candidate who ends in second place, over
the candidate who ends in first place. In a 5-candidate election, they gain
in an average of about 20% of the cases, and lose in an average of about
40%; that is, they lose on average of about twice as often as they gain.
Since this is not even advantageous, Fairvote is flatly incorrect to
repeatedly claim that bullet voting is even “strategic”, let alone
“always... a significant advantage”.
What about other strategies? Correct Approval strategy is, approximately,
to set your approval threshold at the average quality of the candidates whom
you think might win. Unless the election is abnormally close, only two
candidates have a real chance of winning, and of those two one is clearly
leading, so that means you should approve one of the two frontruners and
everyone you like better.
This strategy, unlike Fairvote’s false “strategy”, does indeed give the
voter a significant advantage. Since, as we’ve seen, our definition of
honest Approval voting is probabilistically equivalent to Range voting, the
advantage for strategic voting is the same as it would be in Range. This is
in fact “always ... a significant advantage”. However, several things should
be noted:
-
The actual advantageous strategy is precisely the opposite of the
so-called “strategy” which Fairvote claims will be the pervasive problem
with Approval.
-
If everyone uses their best strategy, the winner will be the Condorcet
winner, if one exists. Far from being a problematic or
pathological result,
this is seen by many as the most democratic result for the society as a
whole.
-
This is actually the same as the “honest” result with our first
proposed definition of honesty.
In conclusion, Fairvote’s critique of strategy under approval voting
suffers from an acute lack of understanding of game theory, and is 180
degrees wrong in several important ways. If Fairvote had confined themselves
to talking about the actions of what they call “strategic actors” --- that
is, candidates and their proxies --- they might have had a point. But for
voters, their supposed “strategy” is just the opposite.
2011/10/10 Jameson Quinn <jameson.quinn at gmail.com>
> I would like to make a detailed critique of the FairVote report they've put
> up at approvalvoting.blogspot.com and rangevoting.com. I believe that
> every single one of the conclusions of that report is dangerously wrong.
> I've created a google doc<https://docs.google.com/document/d/1YgXEqjmhEv05-FHc1PtPs0O9zzwWzKgoy4sBuaEsEcg/edit?hl=en_US>to help make this critique collaboratively. Please add comments to the doc
> to help critique.
>
> Thanks,
> Jameson
>
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20111015/770d296b/attachment-0004.htm>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list