[EM] IRV vs Plurality
Stéphane Rouillon
stephane.rouillon at sympatico.ca
Sun Jan 10 10:57:29 PST 2010
Abd Ul,
from the data you produce, I agree that for the Burlington election, IRV
did produce the same result
FPTP would have produced.
However, nobody can generalize this perticular case to any election.
I agree that in non-partisan election the rallying pattern of defeated
voters does not fit only one typical set of preferences.
However again, a statistical analysis of general preferences shows an
unbalance of preferences, even for non-partisan elections.
Is this unbalance major to the point that IRV could allow a come-back
from another candidate than the plurality winner, or
is this unbalance minor so IRV does not change anything, it depends of
each election.
On a last aspect, I do agree that Condorcet is better than both. And I
admit that , even if I believe that the distribution
of a generalized set of preferences is unbalanced, I have not yet been
able to evaluate or quantify this unbalance.
You can argue that as long that I was not able to quantify by how much
this unbalance occurs (amplitude distribution), it is not
acceptable to claim that this unbalance should allow IRV to find a
"better" winner. But, we do have data of previous elections and
because we both agree that a Condorcet winner is a "better" winner for
this purpose, we can use this reference to evaluate the
combined impact of IRV and the unbalance of the preference sets. Thus,
even if I do dot know the general unbalance distribution,
I can observe that IRV allows more often to obtain a Condoret winner
when plurality fails, than plurality finds a Condorcet winner
when IRV fails. So I claim IRV is more reliable than plurality.
Yours, Stéphane.
Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a écrit :
> At 09:23 AM 1/8/2010, Stéphane Rouillon wrote:
>> > Therefore IRV/STV is no better than plurality, but has extra very
>> > serious flaws, inequities, and vagaries that plurality does not have.
>>
>> I definitively disagree. Plurality is worst than IRV.
>> The flaws that IRV does have are real.
>> But these problems appear very less often than the splitting-vote
>> issue of FPTP.
>
> Stephane, as to abstract theoretical voting systems, naively analyzed,
> and also as to certain real-world situations -- but not others --
> you'd be correct. But notice that Kathy Dopp claimed that IRV is "no
> better than plurality." That's because, in nonpartisan elections, it
> appears that IRV closely reproduces the results of plurality. We have
> tended to think in terms of neat factions, arranged in a spectrum, so
> that you can predict vote transfer patterns with IRV, but nonpartisan
> elections don't work that way.
>
> Generally, in nonpartisan elections in the U.S., vote transfers with
> IRV do not alter the preference order among the remaining candidates.
> Exceptions may occur when races are very close.
>
> On the other hand, in one-third of nonpartisan top-two runoff
> elections, which IRV supposedly simulates, the runner-up in the
> primary goes on to win the runoff, a "comeback election," according to
> a FairVote study. It simply does not happen with IRV.
>
> If you have top-two runoff as a system in use, and you replace it with
> IRV, for nonpartisan elections, you might as well replace it with
> plurality, you will get the same results. That's what is being said.
>
> The recent election in Burlington, Vermont, though, was a partisan
> election. There, Kiss was trailing Wright in first-preference votes,
> but Kiss obtained enough vote transfers from Montrose supporters to
> pass up Wright in the second round of counting. Kiss is Progressive,
> Wright Republican, and Montrose is a Democrat.
>
> But looking at the actual voting data, which is available, we can see
> that Montrose was, in fact, the Condorcet winner, and, as it's been
> pointed out, had a few of the Write supporters voted for Montrose in
> first place instead of in second, Montrose would have won. In other
> words, IRV will punish you (as does plurality) for voting your
> conscience; but with Plurality, it's obvious and everyone would know
> that voting for a Republican in Burlington would be a wasted vote
> (where the leading party is Progressive), so they'd have compromised
> and voted accordingly and Montrose would quite likely have won.
>
> Also, there is good reason to believe that most voters would vote
> according to the same patterns if the method were Bucklin. The ballot
> would have been the same, three-rank. With Bucklin, first round
> results would have been same as IRV, presumably (and assuming that
> nobody did, with IRV, vote strategically already, we can assume that
> with the limited experience with IRV, few would have known to do so).
> Data is from a quite good video Kathy Dopp pointed to,
> http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=bPCS-zWuel8
>
> candidate 1st 2nd
> Montrose 2554 3556
> Kiss 2982 1827
> Wright 3297 1138
> ------------------------------
> 8843 6521
>
> The ballots show third rank data, but my view is that this isn't
> meaningful, many voters may actually be thinking that they are voting
> *against* a candidate by ranking in third place. (There were other
> minor candidates on the ballot and the data in the video is obviously
> oversimplified, but it serves as an example.)
>
> As you can see, no candidate gained a majority in first preference.
> There is serious vote-splitting between Montrose and Kiss, quite
> likely. With IRV, Montrose is eliminated before the second rank votes
> for him are counted. That's 3556 votes that weren't counted!
>
> With Bucklin, all the votes are counted up to the ranks necessary to
> find a majority. The majority is 4422. Adding in the second rank
> votes, we get
>
> Montrose 6110
> Kiss 4809
> Wright 4435
>
> It's not even close! Montrose is the first or second choice of roughly
> three-fourths of the voters. This is Bucklin voting, supremely easy to
> count, just add up the expressed preferences at each rank. It's
> Instant Runoff Approval.
>
> It's true that there might not be such heavy usage of second rank with
> Bucklin (though already 2312 voters "truncated," not expressing a
> second preference). However, there are two possible ways to use Bucklin.
>
> We can generally assume that the votes in the Burlington election were
> sincere. They might not stay that way if Burlington Republican voters
> realize they've been had. Because there are no candidate eliminations
> in Bucklin, though, supporters of minor candidates can safely vote
> their conscience in first rank, because their vote will either help
> their candidate win (unlikely by the conditions) or will cause
> majority failure or will be moot in any case. There is no need for
> Favorite Betrayal, as it's called.
>
> What we have in Burlinton is a three party system, with the
> Republicans being, slightly, the largest. Naturally, they might prefer
> Plurality, except that they know they won't win, because they'd need
> more than a third of the voters. I'd expect Burlington to see a lot of
> runoffs if top-two runoff is used, straight.
>
> But consider top-two runoff with Bucklin used in the primary (and I
> believe that it would be wise to allow write-ins in the runoff and use
> Bucklin there too to prevent the spoiler effect).
>
> The voters would have -- would learn that they have -- a choice: add
> second rank (or third rank) votes if you approve of additional
> candidates, even though you have some stronger preference, or see a
> runoff election. The circumstances actually encourage a form of range
> voting, whether or not you'd add a second or third rank vote depends
> on *how much* you prefer your favorite over the others. This would
> amalgamate to show average preference strength against an actual
> inconvenience. In Bucklin, it's true, if your favorite doesn't win in
> the first round, your second rank vote can cause your favorite to
> lose. IRV allows you to think you are avoiding this possibly
> undesirable outcome, but only because it takes your candidate and
> eliminates him.
>
> Were the Wright voters in Burlington happy because their vote for
> Wright was "protected" from "hurting" Wright?
>
> The 2009 Burlington outcome was truly outrageous, and the votes show
> it. It was a classic center squeeze situation, and the possibility of
> this is precisely why Robert's Rules of Order criticizes IRV and
> considers true repeated balloting (without eliminations!) superior.
> RRO doesn't consider other forms of preferential voting though it
> notes that they exist. I understand that this is because RRO is a
> manual of actual practice, not of theoretical recommendations, but
> there are much, much better voting systems.
>
> Bucklin, to me, has these advantages:
>
> 1. It's been widely used in the U.S., about eighty years ago. It was
> very popular, and much more widely used than the current IRV fad. Why
> was it dumped? Good question. I wish I knew. Most likely answer: it
> worked, and some people didn't like that, such as the Minnesota
> Supreme Court.
>
> 2. It's cheap to canvass. Just add up votes, no complicated handling,
> totals can be summed by precinct easily and transmitted.
>
> 3. It preserves the ability to vote for more than one candidate but
> simultaneously indicate preference, unlike Approval. (Bucklin is
> really Approval voting with a "virtual runoff" feature, so that
> approvals are added in as needed.)
>
> 4. It satisfies the Majority Criterion, which is politically
> desirable. It does not satisfy, technically, the Condorcet Criterion,
> though my sense is that Condorcet failure would be rare and with low
> preference strength.
>
> Bucklin would have allowed the Republican voters in Burlington to vote
> for Wright without suffering the consequential loss of their second
> choice to their lowest preference. Someone should tell them!
>
> I think it's worth looking at how voting strategy might work. Some
> candidates might encourage their supporters not to add lower ranked
> votes for their major opponent. But we already see that many of the
> voters in Burlington did not vote the standard politically predictable
> patterns. We had some Wright supporters voting second rank for Kiss.
> Did that mean that they really preferred Kiss to Montrose. Maybe. Or
> they believed that this would somehow help Wright. Likewise, we had
> Kiss voters voting second rank for Wright. But in both cases these
> numbers were fairly small.
>
> I would indeed expect truncation to increase a bit with Bucklin, maybe
> even a lot. However, not enough, I'm practically certain, to alter the
> result. Second rank voting would have had to decline by 1689 votes for
> Montrose not to gain a majority, from his 3556 second-rank votes as
> shown. He'd still have a plurality. If a majority were required, he'd
> be in the runoff, certainly (whereas with a vote-for-one primary, he
> might be eliminated).
>
> If runoffs are held when there is majority failure, voters should know
> that they should not vote for a candidate, at any rank, unless they
> prefer the election of that candidate to a runoff being held (with its
> costs, inconvenience, and risks). Voters should also be able to leave
> lower ranks blank, deferring the counting of a lower ranked vote until
> later in the process. (It's a little more protection against "harming
> your favorite.") They should also be able to vote for more than one
> candidate at any rank, for reasons I won't explain here, but it is a
> good strategy if you really don't have a strong preference between two
> candidates. But, of course, they should never be able to vote more
> than once for any given candidate, should they mark the same candidate
> in lower ranks, those additional marks would simply be disregarded,
> they should not invalidate the ballot. A vote for a candidate will be
> counted at the highest rank expressed....
>
> ----
> Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list
> info
>
>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list