"Best" candidates, and Social Orderings (was: [EM] Sincere methods)

Juho Laatu juho4880 at yahoo.co.uk
Tue Apr 12 14:54:20 PDT 2005


Hi,

On Apr 4, 2005, at 20:21, Jobst Heitzig wrote:

> We know of course that most often
> one can easily find two measures which do not agree on which candidate
> is "best", so we're left with deciding which measure is most important.
> But what if no measure is "most" important but each is important in 
> some
> sense or other? Then perhaps there is a most important sense in which
> measures can be important... etc...

When we are talking about sincere criteria we could as well leave the 
decision to the community that arranges the election. It is possible 
that different elections are aimed at electing different kind of 
winners. Sometimes the winner maybe should be the one with least 
enemies, sometimes one that is accepted by as many as possible etc. 
There can thus be many different sincere voting methods. This means 
that "best candidate" (and social ordering) is relative to the criteria 
that the community has set for this election.

> in the unlikely case in which the winner becomes
> unavailable between the election and the time of taking office, one
> would rather hold a new election than put the "2nd best" candidate in
> office...

Few observations on this topic:

Yes, there is no need for a single winner method to be able to say who 
was second best. If this ordering is available, it could be possible in 
some cases to reuse the results of the first election if the winner 
becomes unavailable. Many voting methods indicate the result as 
numerical values, in which case it is easy to see what the ordering is. 
The new winner however need not be the second best candidate.

Minmax is one such method. It uses only orderings in the ballot. If the 
winner becomes unavailable one could expect the orderings to stay the 
same even if one of the candidates had not participated in the 
election. (Maybe some people would have ranked more candidates if one 
of their favourites was missing but let's ignore that.) Although the 
rankings would be the same with the remaining candidates, the result 
should be calculated again since it seems natural that one should now 
compare each candidate only against the other remaining candidates, 
i.e. not against the unavailable old winner. For this reason the second 
best (first minmax round) candidate maybe would not be the new winner. 
But we would be able to calculate the winner pretty reliably without 
arranging new elections.

In the example above we had actually two alternative orderings. Maybe 
both can be used, but for different use. (If the used voting method was 
minmax (margins), then the ordering showed how many additional votes 
each candidate would have needed in order to become a Condorcet winner, 
in the case where the first winner (a) is a candidate or (b) is not.)

In some multi winner elections like parliamentary elections the ability 
to reuse the ballots is maybe more useful. It is quite probable that 
some MPs must be replaced between two elections. Some voting methods 
might however recommend to make bigger changes than just elect one new 
candidate to replace the lost one. => Some problems..

> So, I suggest we should drop the idea of "social ordering" altogether

Word "altogether" is a bit strong for me, but surely social preferences 
are more complex than just one ordering.

Best Regards,
Juho






More information about the Election-Methods mailing list