[EM] Saari's Basic Argument

Forest Simmons fsimmons at pcc.edu
Thu Feb 20 16:52:49 PST 2003


On Tue, 18 Feb 2003, Steve Barney wrote:

> Here is a simpler example to illustrate the difference that the order in which
> cyclic and reversal terms are canceled does not matter when using the strictly
> correct method - as opposed to the method used by Forest Simmons and Alex
> Small, and in some of Saari's popular expositions where he is merely trying to
> illustrate basic concepts to a more general audience.

It's true that in my earlier examples I didn't take the decomposition all
of the way to its logical conclusion.  But if you look at my last few
examples, you'll see that I finally hit on a simple method of adding and
subtracting the two kinds of symmetries that reduce each ballot set to a
canonical ballot set consisting of either one faction or two adjacent
factions with positive multiplicity, and all other factions zero.

[Two factions are adjacent if one of them follows the other in the cyclic
order ABC->ACB->CAB->CBA->BCA->BAC->ABC.]

It is easy to prove that this decomposition is unique, since it preserves
the Borda count of each candidate, and the Borda counts determine the
number in each faction when there are two or fewer adjacent factions.  So
the order of application of the symmetries doesn't matter.

As my examples show, this can be done very simply without matrices.

Presumably Saari uses matrices because he wants to develop tools that will
generalize to more than three candidates.

But worrying about the details of symmetry cancellations is to bark up the
wrong tree.

The fact is that in the ballot set 65*ABC+35*BCA the candidates A, B, and
C have the same respective average ranks as they do in the simpler ballot
set 30*ABC+35*BAC , so according to Borda they are equivalent ballot sets,
and B should be the winner of the first election as decisively as in the
second (according to Borda and Saari).

This result may make sense in the context of dispassionate decision making
such as in robotics when a robot is trying to decide what movement to make
or whether a visual image represents the letter U or V.

But in the context of public elections, this supposed equivalence is
almost ludicrous.

So the question is not, "Why is Borda such a great method for public
elections?"

The question is, "Why does the symmetry argument lead us down the wrong
path?"

At least that is the question I was trying to answer (and did answer to
my own satisfaction).

In a nutshell the answer to this question is that the symmetries in the
distribution of ballots are at odds (more often than not) with Saari's
symmetries.

In other words, Saari's transformations do not preserve the natural axes
of symmetry that may (and do) exist in the ballot distributions.

In the above example, the first ballot set 65*ABC+35*BCA consists of two
factions that determine an axis of symmetry.  The second ballot set
35*BAC+30*ABC also consists of two factions along an axis of symmetry, but
this axis is rotated thirty degrees relative to the original axis.

So there is an essential change in the symmetry of the distribution that
the Borda count doesn't detect, and Saari's symmetry transformations
cannot preserve.

[The center of gravity of the distribution is preserved, but the principal
axes of rotation and the radii of gyration are changed.]

For me this insight is sufficient to explain the fallacy of the symmetry
arguments.

Most non-mathematicians don't care one whit about what went wrong with the
symmetry arguments; rather than watch the gory details of an autopsy, they
prefer to move onward and upward.

Forest

----
For more information about this list (subscribe, unsubscribe, FAQ, etc), 
please see http://www.eskimo.com/~robla/em




More information about the Election-Methods mailing list