[EM] The Coming California Single Seat Election

Donald Davison donald at mich.com
Sat Aug 16 02:53:02 PDT 2003


The Coming California Single Seat Election

Greetings List Members,

I have not seen anything said on this list about the coming California
single seat election for governor.

No one is suggesting that their favorite method should be used instead of
Plurality.

What's the problem?  Do you sense your favorite method will fail?

I think both Approval and Condorect would fail this election.

Approval would have a leading candidate, but without a majority of the voters.

Condorect will need about ten thousand pairings, most of which will have
too few lower choices in order to yield valid results.

There's very good chance that the so called `Condorect Winner' will be the
Pluralty Winner.

I suggest using Irving, but that's me.

The author of the article below makes a suggestion.

Donald,

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
http://writ.news.findlaw.com/amar/20030808.html

Governor Davis's Claim to Run as His Own Successor Is Meritless, But
the Fear of a "Fringe" Winner Is Serious:
How the Risk Can Be Eliminated in the Future:
By VIKRAM DAVID AMAR
----
Friday, Aug. 08, 2003

This column is part of a series on the California recall process.
Part One appeared on July 25. - Ed.

On August 4, Governor Gray Davis filed a lawsuit involving the
California recall. In this lawsuit he argues, among other things,
that should a majority of voters opt to recall him, the federal
Constitution still entitles him to be a candidate on the second part
of the ballot - the part that asks voters to fill the recall-created
opening.

The Governor's reasoning is simple: Suppose that, say, on the first
part of the ballot 51% vote for his recall, and 49% oppose it. And
suppose also that no candidate to be Davis' successor on the second
part of the ballot gets 49% support. Davis contends that democracy
requires that he should still remain Governor. After all, more voters
prefer his remaining in office than any other choice.

As I will explain, this simple reasoning is also deeply flawed, and
unlikely to prevail in court (for a number of reasons, including
perhaps a lack of standing by the plaintiffs). But Davis, at least,
has hit a nerve. It is reasonable to worry that a winner could get
much less than 49% support - and not only for the obvious reason that
the field is large, and wide open.

Is there any way to combat this worry and still have a one-day recall
vote? I will show that indeed, there is - though unfortunately, it
could be implemented only in the future, not in time for the Davis
recall/successor election.

The Problem with Governor Davis' Argument

Davis's legal argument on the merits, while intuitively attractive,
has some huge flaws. To begin with, although Davis may be right that
he alone has to get 50% of the vote to be Governor whereas other
aspirants (like Arnold) could win with, say, 30%, on the second part
of the ballot, it is also true that Davis could win the recall with
51% of the vote on the first part even if 80% of the electorate would
prefer Arnold in a head-to-head competition between the two. That is,
just as Davis is excluded from the second part of the ballot, all
others (including Arnold) are excluded from the first part. The two
parts of the ballot effectively involve two distinct questions, so
they are governed by different rules.

More generally, and more importantly, the Davis position disregards
the fact that states exclude people who might be the most popular
candidate from running, and winning, all the time.

Term limits, for instance, can have the effect of preventing someone
(a popular incumbent) who might garner more votes than anyone else
from running. So too do age and residency requirements.

So long as the candidate qualification criteria a state chooses are
non-partisan and reasonable, they should be - and are - upheld in
court. Here, California's interest in excluding Davis from the second
part of the ballot is simple: It's telling someone who was so
contentious that he just got recalled from the State's highest and
most visible office that he now has to sit temporarily on the
sideline, presumably to promote harmony and stability for the State,
and to ensure the State survives whatever crisis brought on the
recall intact. It may be true that should Davis lose on the first
part of the ballot, he is being treated differently than are other
candidates for the governorship, but that is because he is different -
 he is the only person who just got recalled.

In my view, the interest in keeping a recalled person on the sideline
for a moment is actually a stronger interest than the interests in
new blood that justifies absolute term limits (which have been upheld
as constitutional by the state and federal courts in California). For
this reason, Davis' suit should not succeed.

The Fear that the Recall Winner Won't Be a Popular Choice

But even if Davis will lose in court, his suit touches on a real
fear: The fear that the recall election will yield a winner with the
support of only a minority - perhaps a small minority - of California
voters.

As of now (subject, of course, to yet another pending legal
challenge), all one needs to do to have his/her name on the recall
ballot as a possible successor is to come up with 65 signatures and
$3,500. So far, over 300 persons have taken out the paperwork to try
to do so. Tomorrow, August 9, is the final day for successor
candidates to qualify. In the next 24 hours, scores of people may do
so.

That has generated a number of dilemmas. For instance, over the last
month, Democrats have faced a quandary. They say their preferred
outcome is that Davis himself remain in office. But that puts them in
a hard spot: Should they put a competing Democrat on the successor
ballot, or not? Doing so might increase the chances of Davis' recall.
(As of this posting, a few Democrats have indicated they will break
ranks and offer themselves as successor candidates.)

Of course, this dilemma for the Democrats is in part a consequence of
the fact that the recall/succession voting occurs on a single ballot
on a single day. If there were separate elections, the problem would
be obviated: voters (and Democratic party leaders) could make recall,
and successor, decisions separately. But somewhat mystifyingly, the
California Constitution does not allow that option: It prescribes a
single-day recall-and-possible-replacement process.

That's mystifying mostly because this isn't a primary - it's the
general election. Primaries are often won by a plurality winner, and
sometimes even a low-percentage plurality winner. But in the general
election that follows, the winner, in our basically two-party system,
generally receives a majority, or at least something close to it.
That's not likely to be the case in this recall.

As a result, a nagging fear plagues not just Democrats, but many
Californians of every political stripe: What if the winning successor
candidate receives only a small percentage of the vote?

This is very possible, for not only is this a general election, but
there is no runoff. The California Constitution clearly says
that "the candidate who receives a plurality [that is, the most
votes, no matter how few] is the successor." (Emphasis added.)

The winner, thus, may only garner a relatively small percentage of
the overall vote. In a field of 100 candidates, even a person who
gets only about 15% of the vote may stand a decent chance.

And worse still, that winner's percentage of the recall-successor
vote might not reflect his or her actual support among the State's
population -- which might be much lower -- because most people don't
vote. A candidate with narrow but deep support could win, especially
if there is low voter turnout.

Moreover, a plurality system doesn't take account of voters' dislike
for a particular candidate. Thus, the California recall winner not
only may enjoy only narrow support, but also may well be reviled by a
supermajority of voters.

Put another way, a "fringe" candidate could win the recall-successor
election - leaving a huge majority of California voters both
effectively disenfranchised, and deeply dismayed.

In the Future, Single Transferable Voting Should Be Used To Allow
Instant Runoff

Is there any solution to this mess, short of amending the California
Constitution to break up the recall process into two separate
elections on two separate days? Fortunately, the answer is a loud
yes - though it isn't an answer that will be able to help with the
current, troubled recall.

The solution is Single Transferable Voting (STV), or an "Instant
Runoff." My brother, Akhil Reed Amar, and I have explained the system
in an earlier column.

Here's how it works: When a voter casts her ballot, she lists all her
candidate preferences: First choice, second choice, third choice, and
so on. She could still just list her first choice; she's not forced
to rank everyone. But if she wanted to, she could express all the
relative preferences she has.

How does this help? Consider a simple illustration. Suppose that 4
candidates are running in an election in which 100 persons vote. A
gets 31 votes, followed by B with 30 votes, C with 29 votes, and D
with 10 votes. The plurality winner obviously is A. But A wouldn't
necessarily be the winner in an STV system.

STV repeatedly drops the lowest vote getter, but doesn't exclude
those who voted for that person. Instead, it transfers their votes to
their second choice.

So suppose, in our example, that everyone who voted for D ranked C as
their second choice. D (the lowest vote-getter) drops out. But his
ten votes go to C. Now our line-up looks like this: C has 39 votes; A
has 31 votes; B has 30 votes.

Again, the lowest vote getter drops out - this time, it's B. Now B's
30 votes are assigned to those voters' second choices. Suppose 20
named C as a second choice, and 10 listed A. That gives us our new
line-up: C has 59 votes (39 plus 20 second choices), A has 41 (31
plus 10 second choices). And C - not A - is the winner.

That makes sense, for A is considerably less popular than C, when
voters' second choice preferences are taken into account.

STV can be used for virtually any election, but let's focus on
governorships for a moment. In 1998 Jesse Ventura, won the Minnesota
governorship with a bare plurality in a three-way race--37% compared
to 34% for Republican Norm Coleman and 28% for Democrat Skip
Humphrey. But under STV, in comparison, Ventura would have won only
if a very good chunk--almost half--of the Humphrey voters who put
down a second choice picked him and not Coleman. As a result, 63% of
the electorate would not have had their preferences totally ignored.

STV itself is not without problems. It might promote fringe
candidates to run in the first place, because they might get more
initial first-choice votes if supporters knew that their votes would
not be wholly wasted, but quickly reassigned to more major
candidates. But at the end of the day, STV would generally make it
harder for a fringe candidate to win with a simple plurality in a
three-way race, like the one that elected Ventura, or a 30-way race,
as is likely in California.

Elections are the key moments in a democracy when the people
themselves speak, and there is much to be said for allowing them to
speak clearly and communicate their nuanced views - all their
preferences, not just their first choice. STV may be a bit
complicated, but voters can handle it. After all, they're handling
the two current two-part California recall ballot already.

Moreover, the idea of second choice is a simple, familiar one: If
Ruffles are sold out, get Pringles. If Americans can handle this
level of complexity as shoppers, why not as voters? We're not talking
about a butterfly ballot here. This system is intuitive enough that,
with some voter education, it could be used even in a high school
student council election.

Would STV have helped Davis himself - assuming that he, miraculously,
could prevail on his legal claim to be included as a successor
candidate? The answer is almost certainly no.

If 51% of the voters voted to recall Davis, they'd probably rank him
low as a successor choice as well. But they also might prefer him
strongly to a "fringe" candidate - and an STV ballot would let them
register that preference.

Actually, if STV were in the scheme, Davis might be more likely to be
recalled in the first place, because voters who preferred to recall
him - with all their preferences taken into account - would no longer
have to fear ending up with a "fringe" candidate whom they like much
less.

Ironically then, what is good about Davis' lawsuit - the idea that
democracy should mean that voters' preferences are taken into account
insofar as possible - wouldn't be good for Davis. A truly preference-
favoring system like STV might only make his plight worse.

The Hope for STV in the Future: San Francisco's Attempt to Use the
System

If this recall election shapes up to be the debacle some predict,
California may be spurred to use STV the next time. There will
doubtless be resistance: Last week, the State put the kibosh on San
Francisco's efforts to move to STV in its own municipal elections.
But that resistance shouldn't be the last word - STV, in the end, is
the most deeply and truly democratic solution there is.

Voters in San Francisco approved the STV device as a local experiment
17 months ago. But state officials say their plans are still too
complicated and logistically expensive to be implemented in time for
local elections next spring.

State election officials may be right that STV can be expensive and
somewhat foreign right now. But as the recall melee illustrates, so
are the alternatives. And STV's democracy-promoting virtues far
outweigh the modest burdens of its slightly greater complexity.





More information about the Election-Methods mailing list