[EM] An IRVing response
Buddha Buck
bmbuck at 14850.com
Fri Aug 3 11:34:50 PDT 2001
At 10:23 AM 08-03-2001 -0400, Douglas Greene wrote:
>Message: 2
> Date: Fri, 03 Aug 2001 04:03:58 -0500
> From: Randy Kunkee Subject: Re: The Problem(s) with Instant Runoff Voting
Doug: Could you please forward my reply to Randy?
To reply to just one part of this...
>You have given no evidence to argue that the higher ranked candidate will
>lose unfairly, or that a lower ranked candidate will win unfairly. It is no
>more difficult than regular elections to turn in counts that can be summed,
>and I have demonstrated that in other postings to this mailing list, and
>will gladly and easily demonstrate it to any who ask. Briefly, all you have
>to do is turn in counts for each unique set of rankings. Eg. there will be
>a certain number of L-D-R, L-R-D, R-L-D votes, etc. So the actual number of
>counts turned in might go up a lot, but are certainly manageable. Such
>counts could be published and anybody who wants to could apply the
>elimination process themselves to check the results.
There were 13 candidates on the Florida Presidential ballot in
2000. Assuming only full rankings, that means that there are 13!
(6,227,020,800) different unique rankings. Obviously, since there were
less than 5 million votes cast in Florida, not all 6 billion different
unique rankings will need to be tallied. Perhaps only a few thousand
different unique rankings will need to be tallied, because of people voting
identically.
However, I find that I am not swayed by arguments that suggest we can
simplify counting by tallying individual categories when the theoretical
number of categories we have to keep track of exceeds the voting population
by several orders of magnitude.
As for a lower-ranked candidate unfairly winning, Imagine this scenario:
There are three candidates, Larry (a liberal), Melissa (a moderate), and
Chris (a conservative). Because of the perceived one-dimensional nature of
US politics, anyone who prefers Larry to Melissa is going to prefer Melissa
to Chris, and vice versa. However, some people who prefer Melissa to
either of the others will prefer Larry to Chris, and vice versa. That
means there are four basic voting blocks:
Larry>Melissa>Chris (The LMC block)
Chris>Melissa>Larry (The CML block)
Melissa>Chris>Larry (The MCL block)
Melissa>Larry>Chris (The MLC block).
The electorate is fairly polarized, so about 70% of the electorate prefers
Larry or Chris over Melissa, and are about evenly split. The voting blocks
work out to be:
35% Larry>Melissa>Chris
35% Chris>Melissa>Larry
x% Melissa>Larry>Chris
y% Melissa>Chris>Larry
Looking solely at pairs of candidates, we note that 65% of the voters
prefer Melissa to Chris, and so if Larry wasn't involved, Melissa would
win. Likewise we note that 65% of the voters prefer Melissa to Larry, and
so if Chris wasn't involved, Melissa would again win. Both victories would
be touted as "landslides". Melissa is a better, more supported choice than
-either- of the candidates, when the entire set of preferences are taken
into account.
However, because Melissa only got 30% of the first-place votes, Melissa
gets eliminated, and one of the other two wins. This is going to upset 65%
of the voters, who though Melissa was a better choice. Only the original
35% who supported the winner are happy with the choice.
This is a concrete example of this problem with IRV.
>I consider IRVs similarities to the current plurality system an advantage --
>in the people understand it and will accept it. It also does not have to be
>the final solution, but will be an improvement over what we already have.
>
>Randy Kunkee
>The Instant Runoff Project
>www.instantrunoff.org
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list