Head to Head Comparison of Election Methods
Bart Ingles
bartman at netgate.net
Thu May 27 20:07:27 PDT 1999
Ron Tannenwald wrote:
> [snip] I fully agree that the "winner" should have majority
> approval
> from the electorate.It is assumed that ballot truncation is a strategic
> ploy and
> that the voter has no preference among the candidates omitted,hence the
> remaining points are distributed equally.But ballot truncation may be the
> voter's way of expressing disapproval of those truncated.Assume,for a moment,
> this to be the case and consider the following example:
>
> 20% 20% 39% 21%
> --- --- --- ---
>
> A A B C
> B C
> C B
>
> Most of the familiar methods (Plurality,Instant Runoff,Condorcet ,and
> Dumais)
> would declare A the victor. Candidate A has only 40% approval. Candidate B has
> nearly the number of first place tallies,79% approval, and is the first or
> second choice of 59%.If a winner is to be annointed I think it should be B.
In general, it is not possible to tell how the voters would have voted
under Approval from looking at a ranked example. You need information
about the strength of the voters' preferences. The result above could
have come from either of the two rated scenarios:
Scenario I:
Rating:
100 80 60 40 20 0
----------------------------------
20% A B C
20% A C B
39% B AC
21% C AB
Scenario II:
Rating:
100 80 60 40 20 0
----------------------------------
20% A B C
20% A C B
39% B AC
21% C AB
In the first instance, A would get 40% approval, C would recieve close
to 41%, and B somewhere between 42 and 59%.
In the second case, the A voters would cooperate by truncating. The
Approval vote would be the same as a Plurality vote (or most other
methods).
This assumes the only tactical voting in the ranked example was
truncation.
> I am NOT a fan of Approval Voting.It was first proposed in the decade after
> Arrow's famous result appeared.It is simple (to understand and implement) and
> technically is independent of irrelevant alternatives which seems to set it
> apart from all ranking methods.Its main proponent Professor Steven Brams of
> NYU
> writes research articles which purport to mathematically prove its superiority
> under the assumption that voter's feelings about candidates are
> dichotomous. This hypothesis is preposterous! No voter's attitudes about
> candidates are dichotomous.I would approve of Prof. Brams in a two-way race
> against an Adolf
> Hitler and not approve of him in a two-way contest against an Honest Abe
> Lincoln. Furthermore,if my favored candidate withdrew from the race I might
> very
> well change my non-approval of another to approval;so,in actuality,this
> method is not independent of irrelevant alternatives.Approval Voting
> violates
> the majority criterion (sometimes dramatically).To overcome this major
> shortcoming voters are forced to employ strategies that hide their true
> feelings.
That last statement is true of any method, given the right
circumstances. At least under Approval there is never a reason not to
include a vote for your first choice.
> Simplicity is about the only thing in its favor(but Plurality
> Voting is
> even simpler.)
>
> To justify my choice of a voting procedure let me set forth some criteria
> I feel are necessities.
>
> 1.Majority Criteria (i.e. if a candidate is the first choice of a majority,
> that candidate wins)
The concept of Majority may not be as solid as it appears. Under
Plurality, a "first-choice majority" can include tactical votes from
voters who actually preferred someone else. This is also true of
Instant Runoff and Bucklin. I think the Condorcet methods escape this,
but I disagree with this class of methods for other reasons.
Altering Blake's Bucklin example slightly:
30 D R F
15 D F R
11 F R D
44 R D F
The first round ends with 45-D, 11-F, 44-R
The second round ends with 89-D, 75-R, and 26-F.
Knowing this, the F voters should use the tactic of voting for R, then
F:
30 D R F
15 D F R
11 R F D
44 R D F
Now R has 55 first-choice votes. Is this the real majority, or is one
of the 89-D and 75-R votes in the sincere example the real majority?
Regards,
Bart Ingles
> 2.The winner must have the approval of a majority of voters.
>
> 3.The method should be simple to explain,understand,and implement.
>
> With the understanding that no method is ideal,my preference would be
> Bucklin voting with the proviso that should no candidate receive majority
> approval the election is void and no present candidate can run in the new
> election.
>
> Bucklin voting is certainly simple and has been used
> historically;voters immediately saw that their lower choices might hurt
> their favorites(a property common to most ranking systems without
> elimination, but not so obvious) and so many voted bullets.The second part
> of my scheme is meant to discourage strategic
> truncation of ballots.Voters do so now at their peril.
>
> Respectfully,
> .
>
> Ronald Tannenwald
> Chairperson, Mathematics Department
> UMass Dartmouth
> North Dartmouth MA, 02747
> (508) 999-8746
> Fax: 508-910-6917
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list