[EM] criteria compliance and strategic vulnerability
Chris Benham
chrisbenham at bigpond.com
Thu May 19 08:48:18 PDT 2005
James,
I've looked over your "Voting Methods:definitions and criteria" page,
and to my mind there are
quite a few things that are conspicuous by their absence. The way you
have categorized the different
criteria may not be ideal, because some of them relate to more than one
of "majority rule", "defeat strength"
and "strategy".
There is no version of Minimal Defense, or the Plurality criterion.
My "No Zero-Information Strategy" and
"Weak Burial Resistance" criteria are absent. (The latter is very
closely related to your Dominant Mutual Third
criterion.)
There are no "Gross" versions of Condorcet and Smith.What do you think
is the advantage of amalgamating
Later-no-Harm and Later-no-Help into the "Later preference criterion"?
IMO, two "consistency" criteria that are of greater practical importance
than the ones you list are "Mono-add-plump"
and "Mono-append".
Regarding the methods, I think it is a bit incongruous that you list a
few rankings methods and Approval alongside
one rankings/ratings hybrid (Cardinal Pairwise, which uses a cumbersome
double ballot); but no rankings/approval
hybrid methods. I suggest you list AWP, DMC and AM.
I have a few comments about some of the entries in your "Strategy
definition summary" table.
I am not a big fan of Approval, but I wouldn't say that
Compromising-compression was strictly "forced". That is
only true of voters who wish to approve candidates other than those they
sincerely rank equal-first.
Likewise Burial-compression is only "forced" for voters who wish to not
approve candidates other than those they
sincerely rank equal-last.
You don't distinguish between ER-IRV(fractional) and ER-IRV(whole).
Which one does the table refer to?
In any case they both should definitely have a higher number than does
plain IRV in the "paradoxical" row, and the
number for ER-IRV(whole) should be 4 or 5.
Maybe WV should have a higher number than Margins in the
"compromising-compression" row, because in WV
but not Margins the voter can have a zero-information incentive to
equal-rank at the top.
Probably WV should have a lower number than Margins in the
"compromising-reversal" row, because sometimes
in WV compromising-compression can be an effective "defensive strategy"
but to achieve the same effect those voters
in Margins have to compromise-reverse.
There can sometimes be objective measures of how badly a method fails a
criterion. For example, "CDTT,X" (where "X"
is a Later-no-Harm method), which orders the candidates according to X
and then elects the highest ordered in the CDTT,
strictly meets Later-no-Harm unless there are more than three candidates
in a majority-strength top cycle (very very unlikely
to occur in practice). These methods fail Smith(Net) and the Plurality
criterion but meet Smith(Gross), and with all the voters
having no incentive to truncate then those criterion failures are very
unlikely to occur in practice.
In this context, my favourite X is IRV because it is the only
Later-no-harm method that both has no clone problem and meets
Weak Burial Resistance.
I found some of the colours on the dark background a bit hard to read
unless I highlighted everything (by right-clicking on
"Select All").
Chris Benham
Abbreviations...
compromising-c: compromising-compression
compromising-r: compromising-reversal
burying-c: burying-compression
burying-r: burying-reversal
c forced: compression is forced by the ballot
nER-IRV: IRV without equal ratings allowed
ER-IRV: IRV with equal ratings allowed
WV: winning votes
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list