<div dir="ltr"><div dir="ltr"><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0px 0px 0px 0.8ex;border-left:1px solid rgb(204,204,204);padding-left:1ex"><div dir="ltr">I'm all for convincing people of the need for reform first and foremost and then convincing them of specific methods later. Now, you could argue that certain reforms would turn the public off the idea of structural change once and for all, and I'd take those concerns seriously.</div><div></div></blockquote><div>I don't think convincing people the current system is bad is very helpful unless you have a better alternative. People tend to flail about and pick the first system they think of or hear about—like IRV—and sometimes even pick a disastrous system like Borda. After a state or city picks a new system, they usually stick with it for decades out of pure inertia, meaning it locks us out of systems that actually improve the election's results. If nothing else, promoting these systems wastes time and effort that could be better-spent elsewhere.</div><div><br></div><div>It's also easier to argue for a better policy than a worse one. If reform movements didn't have so many problems with Nobel-laureate economists and political scientists writing newspaper articles and papers about IRV not working that well, and didn't have major disasters like Alaska's 2022 election to deal with, things would probably be an easier sell.</div><div><br></div><div>It's worth noting we have a case study of this. During the Progressive Era in the 1910s, lots of US cities adopted new voting systems, typically STV. These rules survived only a few decades before repeal. Most famously, in New York, STV caused so many monotonicity failures that the city decided to kill the only large-scale proportional representation system in the United States after officials derided it for being a lottery.</div><div><br></div><div>It's taken 100 years for the electoral reform movement to recover and get a second chance. I don't want to wait another 100 years for a reform that might actually stick this time.</div></div></div><br><div class="gmail_quote"><div dir="ltr" class="gmail_attr">On Sun, Mar 24, 2024 at 4:12 PM Michael Garman <<a href="mailto:michael.garman@rankthevote.us" target="_blank">michael.garman@rankthevote.us</a>> wrote:<br></div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0px 0px 0px 0.8ex;border-left:1px solid rgb(204,204,204);padding-left:1ex"><div dir="ltr">>
Note that I'm not asking if you think the fool me twice problem is<br>likely to happen with IRV. Just whether it's reasonable for someone who<br>thinks enacting a (to his mind) flawed method can cause a backlash, to<br>not go for that method.<div><br></div><div>For sure. It's a reasonable argument.</div><div><br></div><div>I think the principal consideration to bear in mind is where the opposition is coming from and what their arguments are. If I were an activist in a community where the prevailing opinion was that reform was necessary, I'd be all for having a debate about the merits of different methods and the relative logistical complications they might pose.</div><div><br></div><div>My concern right now is that most people aren't open to <i>any</i> reform, and if the public-facing image they see is a reform movement that can't even agree on a measure to push, they'll be even more skeptical. Not that we can't or shouldn't have these debates, of course. But I think the Seattle 2022 example -- where the IRV supporters were at fault! -- is exactly the opposite of what we want to happen. Overall support for the first part of the question -- the one that was essentially "should we scrap FPP?" was way lower than it would have been if there hadn't been confusion over competing proposals and the impression of a fractured reform community.</div><div><br></div><div>I'm all for convincing people of the need for reform first and foremost and then convincing them of specific methods later. Now, you could argue that certain reforms would turn the public off the idea of structural change once and for all, and I'd take those concerns seriously.</div></div><br><div class="gmail_quote"><div dir="ltr" class="gmail_attr">On Sun, Mar 24, 2024 at 8:07 PM Kristofer Munsterhjelm <<a href="mailto:km_elmet@t-online.de" target="_blank">km_elmet@t-online.de</a>> wrote:<br></div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0px 0px 0px 0.8ex;border-left:1px solid rgb(204,204,204);padding-left:1ex">On 2024-03-20 09:57, Michael Garman wrote:<br>
> To be clear, I am by no means a believer that IRV is the only reform <br>
> worth pursuing, or that it’s anywhere close to the perfect system.<br>
> <br>
> Where Michael and I disagree is on the role of pragmatism. I believe <br>
> that any time an alternative to plurality voting is on the ballot, <br>
> voters should support it. I think the folks in Eugene, Oregon, should <br>
> vote yes on STAR. I think more places should try out approval. Beyond <br>
> those three, I read this list because I enjoy learning about completely <br>
> new and different systems that would be fascinating to see in practice <br>
> somewhere one day. But in a place where citizens are asked for an up or <br>
> down vote on IRV vs. FPTP, I don’t see how you can defend voting for the <br>
> worst possible system because the proposed reform isn’t exactly what <br>
> you’d like.<br>
<br>
What do you think about the following reasoning? Call it the "fool me <br>
twice" problem.<br>
<br>
Suppose that a jurisdiction is considering switching from FPTP to Borda. <br>
The main organization is heavily marketing Borda as the one ranked <br>
voting system, equating the ranked ballot format to Borda, the method.<br>
<br>
Meanwhile, an organization promoting MDDA (majority defeat <br>
disqualification approval) is slowly growing. Someone (call him John) <br>
favors MDDA and thinks that due to Borda's clone problem, it will <br>
quickly be repealed. Then, he reasons, the jurisdiction will think that <br>
ranking equals Borda, so that when some other ranked method is proposed <br>
(MDDA, say), they will remember the failure of Borda that led to its <br>
repeal and say "no; fool me twice, shame on me".<br>
<br>
Suppose for the sake of argument that there is a considerable chance <br>
that Borda would be repealed if it were enacted, and a lesser chance <br>
that MDDA would. Is then John in the right to withhold his support for <br>
Borda? Would it be right for the MDDA organization to try to counter the <br>
Borda organization's marketing by saying more ranked methods exist, even <br>
if doing so reduces the chance that Borda is enacted?<br>
<br>
Note that I'm not asking if you think the fool me twice problem is <br>
likely to happen with IRV. Just whether it's reasonable for someone who <br>
thinks enacting a (to his mind) flawed method can cause a backlash, to <br>
not go for that method.<br>
<br>
-km<br>
</blockquote></div>
----<br>
Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="https://electorama.com/em" rel="noreferrer" target="_blank">https://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br>
</blockquote></div>