<html><head><meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html charset=utf-8"></head><body style="word-wrap: break-word; -webkit-nbsp-mode: space; -webkit-line-break: after-white-space;" class=""><br class=""><div><blockquote type="cite" class=""><div class="">On 02 Nov 2016, at 22:31, Michael Ossipoff <<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>> wrote:</div><br class="Apple-interchange-newline"><div class=""><div dir="ltr" class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class="">Well, suppose that all the candidates are excellent, but some qualify as "very best excellent" and perfect.<br class=""><br class=""></div>If you're like me, you'll just approve the "very best excellent" near-perfect ones, instead of needing to choose among the merely excellent ones<br class=""><br class="">.If one of merely excellent ones wins, then just take a chance on which merely excellent candidate wins.<br class=""></div></div></div></div></div></div></div></blockquote><div><br class=""></div><div><div>I might vote that way if all candidates were excellent and some even better. I think this describes a situation where the election is not very competitive, and as a result I have no need to apply the most efficient strategy that I know. I probably trust that also other voters have similar feelings and plans, and as a result the best / most approved candidate will win.</div><div><br class=""></div><div>My problem here is that political elections are typically very competitive, and as a result most voters are interested in casting a vote that is as strong as possible. Voters try to make sure that their vote will help their favourites and absolutely not help the worst candidates and the strongest competitors of their favourites.</div><div><br class=""></div><div>In elections that are not competitive one could of course move towards different methods and strategies, like approval based on sincere individual preferences (instead of expected candidate strength based strategy), or sincere range.</div><div class=""><br class=""></div></div><br class=""><blockquote type="cite" class=""><div class=""><div dir="ltr" class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class=""><div class=""><br class=""></div>But what if, due to equal candidate merit spacing, there's a gradual uniform gradation between those 2 sets, making it not so easy to say where to draw the line, and the approval-cutoff?<br class=""><br class=""></div>Two possibilities suggest themselves:<br class=""><br class=""></div>1. If there are some that are definitely perfect, and some that are in a a gradation-region where it's difficult to draw the line, then why settle for "maybe perfect". Just approve the definitely perfect ones.<br class=""></div></div></div></div></blockquote><div><br class=""></div><div>That still does not offer the best competitive strategy.</div><br class=""><blockquote type="cite" class=""><div class=""><div dir="ltr" class=""><div class=""><div class=""><br class=""></div>2. But if that uniform gradation extends all the way to the top, then, within that gradation, choose an Approval cutoff that's as close as possible to the expected CWs, or as close as possible to the expected winner-merit, however estimated.<br class=""></div></div></div></blockquote><div><br class=""></div><div>But now we are getting closer. You should set your approval cutoff to that side of the CWs (or expected winner) where the second strongest candidate is (again assuming that you are competitive).</div><br class=""><blockquote type="cite" class=""><div class=""><div dir="ltr" class=""><div class=""><br class="">But don't worry--We won't have to deal with that problem for a little while.<br class=""></div></div></div></blockquote><div><br class=""></div><div>But I guess whoever will one day use approval in competitive spirit should have a clear understanding of the strategies.</div><br class=""><blockquote type="cite" class=""><div class=""><div dir="ltr" class=""><div class=""><br class=""></div><div class="">Michael Ossipoff<br class=""></div></div><div class="gmail_extra"><br class=""><div class="gmail_quote">On Wed, Nov 2, 2016 at 2:49 PM, Michael Ossipoff <span dir="ltr" class=""><<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>></span> wrote:<br class=""><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex"><p dir="ltr" class="">(Replying farther down)</p><span class=""><p dir="ltr" class="">On Nov 2, 2016 11:19 AM, "Juho Laatu" <<a href="mailto:juho.laatu@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">juho.laatu@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
><br class="">
><br class="">
>> On 02 Nov 2016, at 19:51, Michael Ossipoff <<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> Well, for the reason you describe, pre-election polls would be of questionable value.<br class="">
><br class="">
> It is hard to avoid pre-election polls since they are pretty much a norm in modern democracies. Approval voters also need some pre-election polls to use the normal approval strategy</p>
</span><p dir="ltr" class="">(endquote)</p><p dir="ltr" class="">But what I'm saying is that "normal Approval strategy"<br class="">
won't be needed unless you're voting in Utopia.</p><p dir="ltr" class="">...because, if unless all the candidates qualify equally as very-best & perfect for you, the completely easy strategy of approving your top-set will be optimal.</p><div class=""><br class=""></div></blockquote></div></div></div></blockquote><div><br class=""></div><div>You seem to propose that one should not use the (well known, ideal) normal approval strategy. I'm thinking that those voters that use the normal strategy (based on sufficiently accurate estimates on support of key candidates) will have more power than those that do not vote that way. I guess you were saying that in some elections finding the ideal competitive strategy might be less important to the voter than just approving those candidates that the voter finds most approvable.</div><div><br class=""></div><div>In competitive elections, if voters can use some poll information to make their vote stronger, they are likely to do so. In the proposed strategy there is of course the small problem that poll information may not always be totally reliable and completely accurate. Also in such cases the voters might get some guidance from their parties, or they might adjust the poll results themselves to make them more credible.</div><div><br class=""></div><div>Using personal preference information only, and not paying any attention to available poll results, does not make much sense if one assumes that voters are competitive. I however assume that some voters will do so, even in competitive approval elections.</div><div><br class=""></div><div>Jumping once more back to the proposed strategy. I note that any available poll information could influence voting decisions in competitive approval elections. The approval cutoff point of those voters that use the "normal" approval strategy can be moved by influencing the poll results by giving misleading information in the polls.</div><div><br class=""></div><div>Juho</div><div><br class=""></div><br class=""><blockquote type="cite" class=""><div class=""><div class="gmail_extra"><div class="gmail_quote"><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex"><span class="HOEnZb"><font color="#888888" class=""><p dir="ltr" class="">Michael Ossipoff<br class=""><br class=""></p></font></span><div class="HOEnZb"><div class="h5"><p dir="ltr" class=""> unless having only results of the previous election, or having 0-info available, is acceptable.<br class="">
><br class="">
>> Much more reliable would be the result in the previous election. _That_ is the reliable poll. ...Even if the candidates are new, it still informs about parties.<br class="">
><br class="">
> Yes, maybe outdated, but quite sincere / reliable info. However, a total poll ban is maybe not very probable in most countries.<br class="">
><br class="">
>> Though there _might_ not be a top-set for most people, in an authentic political system, I was mistaken to imply that there wouldn't be one:<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> Even without the odious Republocrats, even no one odious to the 99% could win, and so no one like that would be in the election, there's still a good variety among Progressive parties & candidates.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> Probably they're all ok, but there's still likely be a subset who are significantly closer to, perceived by you as the very best.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> So, there'd still be a top-set, even though the "bottom-set" is no longer odious.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> But what if there weren't, because _all_ the candidates quality equally as the very best.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> Only then will there be no top-set.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> Only then will you not have the thoroughly simple optimal strategy of approving only your top-set.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> But the resulting strategy "dilemma" would be a pretty nice dilemma, wouldn't you agree?<br class="">
><br class="">
> If I understood you right, we are talking about a pure two-party or two-faction system vs. a richer set of candidates. I'm used to having a richer set of candidates, and I like that approach. But if someone strongly wants a two-party system, that's ok too. If one wants to change the system, there should be a wide consensus and good understanding on what the target system should be like (e.g. a proportional multiparty system that covers all administration and representative bodies).<br class="">
><br class="">
>> You'd then have to estimate where the CWs is. Or lacking information about that, or lacking a CWs, you'd have to estimate the expected winner-merit, & approve down to there.<br class="">
><br class="">
> Yes, and here poll strategies could be a problem in approval. That may not be a major problem though, as I already noted. But on the other hand it may make sense even to individual voters to follow the poll strategy that I proposed. Maybe it would be possible to compare the poll results to the actual election results and roughly estimate how many voters used strategies in the polls.<br class="">
><br class="">
> Juho<br class="">
><br class="">
>> But my point here is that you have a top-set, & the thoroughly easy simple strategy of approving (only) that top-set, unless it's the utopianly happy circumstance of all the candidates qualifying as "very best" and equally being just what you most want.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>><br class="">
>> ...& when that's so, choosing among them would be a very nice dilemma.<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> Michael Ossipoff<br class="">
>><br class="">
>> On Nov 2, 2016 10:09 AM, "Juho Laatu" <<a href="mailto:juho.laatu@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">juho.laatu@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>>> On 02 Nov 2016, at 18:13, Michael Ossipoff <<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> On Wed, Nov 2, 2016 at 3:27 AM, Juho Laatu <<a href="mailto:juho.laatu@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">juho.laatu@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>>> Since educated approval voting is based on voting strategically (constructively, not maliciously) so that each voter tries to make a difference between some leading candidates, approval is more vulnerable to deceptive poll information than many other methods. Most voters are expected to vote strategically, and voting strategy will be derived from the available poll information. This strategic vulnerability applies to all polls, not only approval based polls.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> It depends on what you mean by "strategically". You mean electing the best candidate you can, which amounts to identiflying the CWs & approving down to hir.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> Here "strategically" means setting your approval threshold so that your vote is likely to have maximum impact on the results. That typically means approving at least one of the frontrunners, and not approving at least one of them. That's the normal approval voting "strategy". (In the polls I assumed a different strategy than this "normal" strategy to be applied.)<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> But,a s I've been repeatedly saying, for progressiive voters, in this country there is a clear & obvious top-set: The progressive candidates. (I've also told why it's in the interest of a big majority of the population to elect a progressive government).<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> So, for progressives, which means for pretty much anyone who knows what's in their best interest, it's a top-set/bottom-set election.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> For such an election, the kind of strategy you're talking about is entirely irrelevant. The optimal strategy is simple: Approve (only) your top-set.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> Did you refer here to the normal approval strategy in the elections, or to the different (more deceptive) strategy in the polls? My intention was to say that in the polls one could use some other strategy than the normal approval strategy, but in the actual approval election the normal approval strategy would apply (but with falsified input information).<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> (I may not be completely familiar with all the details of the progressives vs. others set-up in the U.S. elections.)<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> In a different & better society, with honest elections and media, maybe the candidates of progressives' bottom-set would be so unwinnable that they'd no longer be in the elections. ...and it would no longer be a top-set/bottom-set election. But then, with the combination of honest elections and honest, open media, it would also be a lot more obvious who's the CWs. Absent a top-set, the best strategy is to approve down to the CWs, if s/he's identifiable. ...and s/he likely would be, then.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> Without a top-set/bottom-set situation, and if the CWs weren't identifiable, or if there weren't one, then a 0-info expectation-maximizing strategy would be the next best. ...approving down to the expected winner-merit.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> The poll strategy that I proposed was aimed at hiding the CWs (Condorcet winner in sincere opinions) and/or strongest approval candidates from the voters. That way you can make the voters base their (normal approval) strategy on misinformation. In the example that made B the winner instead of the majority favourite (and CWs) A. We thus didn't have 0-info, but some insincere poll information instead.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> I've been discussing ways of estimating that. <br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> Forest mentioned something that shows that there's a sense in which no election is really 0-info:<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> The 0-info strategies for expectation-maximization all assume some knowledge of at least the range of where the voters are, inferred from the range of where the candidates are. But,ito the extent that you know that range, is it really 0-info?<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> Forest pointed out that the middle of the distribution is going to be less than halfway to the far end of it, from wherever you are in it.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> That gives you at least some estimate-information about where the voter-median is. ...where the CWs is.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> So that would suggest that, whatever the dimensionality, one shouldn't approve past the candidate midrange, and should, in fact, approve only down to some unknown distance short of it.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> My example was a pure one dimensional example. But the same strategy can work also in some more complex opinion spaces. The intended winner must however be to some extent centrist, since the strategy requires some other candidate(s) to be more disliked (than the planned strategic winner) to the voter group(s) whose voting strategy (or actually the input parameters of the voting strategy, namely the perceived CWs and/or approval forerunners) the strategy tries to modify.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> The intended strategic winner should thus have each set of voters (to be fooled) on one side, and a false potential winner on the opposite side. One can not use very many dimensions / directions / target groups since one can not promote candidates that are close to the target voter groups groups (in the polls). It may however often be sufficient and most efficient to fool only one or two groups of voters to win the election.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> My suggestion to approve past that midrange, by an amount that increases with the dimenaionality, even if all the candidates are in the same general direction from you, makes the questionable assumption that, even from there, the voter-distribution will likely take the shape of a section of a circle or sphere centered where you are.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> So that questionable assumption explains the contradiction between my suggestion to approve past the midrange when the dimensionality is greater than 1, vs what Forest pointed out...that the voter-median, the CWs, can be expected to be closer than the candidate/voter midrange.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> But all this has nothing to do with our current (supposed) political system, in which there's a clear, definite & obvious top-set for anyone who wants the country to be better for the 99%.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> Just approve your top-set, the progressive candidates.<br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> Michael Ossipoff<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> I guess in the U.S. the political set-up is so well known that the proposed strategy would not work very well right after changing the election method from the current one to approval. I mean that it would not be credible to market one of the two strong candidates as a weak candidate in the hope of making the opposite side approve also him/her in the hope of not electing some even worse extreme candidate. But maybe in time, after also other candidates will be seen as potential winners, the situation would change, and approval polling strategies could be successfully used.<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> Juho<br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> <br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>>> <br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>> On the other hand, although this vulnerability is very obvious and easy to apply in theory, I lean in the direction that in typical public elections strategic voting or strategic polling is not as big of a problem as one might think based on all the theoretical threat scenarios that are often discussed on this list. In all elections voters are likely to have also incentives to vote sincerely. In the mentioned example many B supporters may prefer to always approve B (also in the polls, not only in the actual election), and B supporters may not like approving also C in the polls, just to make it sure that B will be seen as a more popular candidate than C. Such tendencies to promote one's true favourite are related also to longer term developments, like keeping the number of votes up also in the following elections, and trying give as much positive push as possible to one's favourite party, current representatives and candidates even if they are not elected this time.<br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>> In real life TTR elections I have not observed any strong tendency to vote strategically at the first round. Some probably do vote strategically (one of the potential winners), but I guess it is more typical to just vote sincerely at the first round. Also in plurality elections, where strategic voting (of one of the two leading candidates) is often the only rational thing to do (from a theoretical point of view, if one's only goal is to win this particular election), many people still prefer to vote sincerely.<br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>> I would expect these sincere tendencies to apply also in approval elections. I.e. poll strategies would not be so strong that they would in practice lead to such rampant strategic behaviour in the polls that would have a serious impact on voting behaviour in the actual election. This applies even more to other relatively strategy free methods like Condorcet. I believe strategic voting would not be a problem in typical large public Condorcet elections. As I have mentioned a few times, I'm still waiting for someone to present some practical strategic voting guidance that could be applied in typical large public Condorcet elections. So far there is none. The existence of such valid strategic voting guidance depends also on how strongly the public approves / rejects strategic behaviour. But as said, I have not seen any good guidance that would work even in the most strategy friendly societies (where voters are happy to vote as told by the party strategists, and where people who do not use all available deceptive strategies are considered to be fools).<br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>> Juho<br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>> On 02 Nov 2016, at 07:29, Michael Ossipoff <<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>> Ok, now I get it. Sure, that's the trouble with a pre-election poll to get information for voting. Deceptive insincere voting in the informational poll.<br class="">
>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>> That's a nagging doubt that probably is felt by everyone who suggests such pre-election informational polls. <br class="">
>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>> Thanks for bringing it up, and for clarifying it for me. I guess I missed the fact that you were talking about voting in the poll, and were discussing that deceptive poll-voting problem.<br class="">
>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>> On Tue, Nov 1, 2016 at 2:36 PM, Juho Laatu <<a href="mailto:juho.laatu@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">juho.laatu@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>> On 01 Nov 2016, at 20:07, Michael Ossipoff <<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>> B, as a 2nd choice, is at the borderline for approval, if the ">" have uniform magnitude for a particular faction.<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>> I didn't assume anything very specific on the strength of the preferences in the sincere preferences. Unless the preference strengths are not totally radical (e.g. A>>>>>>>>>>>>B>C), B can be presented to the A supporters as an acceptable compromise candidate (when compared to the even worse C).<br class="">
>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>> Approving hir or not is ok.<br class="">
>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>> I don't understand why you say that the B voters shouldn't approve B.<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>> That's because A supporters should be made not to think that A and B are the leading candidates (as they are based on the sincere preferences), but that A and C are the leading candidates. If A supporters believe that A and C are the leading candidates (because of the strategic answers to the approval polls), some of them will approve also B, and with good probability that makes B the winner in the actual approval election (although A supporters have 51% majority and they would win if all of them simply bullet voted).<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>> The strategic plan is thus to hide the fact that in sincere opinions A and B are clearly the two leading candidates, and make the A supporters think that C is the second strongest candidate. That's why it makes sense not to approve one's favourite (B) in the approval polls. In the actual approval election B supporters will naturally all approve B.<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>> Juho<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>> Michael Ossipoff<br class="">
>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>> On Nov 1, 2016 1:41 AM, "Juho Laatu" <<a href="mailto:juho.laatu@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">juho.laatu@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> I generated one example of strategic polling in approval elections with approval polls. No specific claims included. Just some food for your thoughts.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Sincere preferences:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> 51: A>B>C<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> 49-c: B>C>A<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> c: C>B>A<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Approval poll results:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> 51-ab: {A}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> ab: {A, B}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> 49-c-x: {B, C} (strategic, see Note 1)<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> x: {C} (strategic and insincere, see Note 2)<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> c-cb: {C}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> cb: {C, B}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Note 1: All B supporters should approve C.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Note 2: Some B supporters should possibly not approve B. The intention is to keep the approval level of B (49-x+cb) high enough to make B look like a credible potential winner, but not as high as the approval level of C.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Approval election results:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> 51-ab': {A}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> ab': {A, B}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> 49-c-bc: {B} (can be sincere)<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> bc: {B, C} (can be sincere)<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> c-cb': {C}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> cb': {C, B}<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> The strategic target of B supporters is to keep ab' and cb' as large as possible. The A supporters should approve also B as a lesser evil, to avoid C that seems to be very popular in the polls. The C supporters should approve also B as a lesser evil, to avoid A that seems to be very popular in the polls. Preferably ab' > ab, and cb' > cb.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Most voters know that (in sincere preferences) B is some sort of a middle candidate between A and C.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> The best strategy (that we know but voters do not) of the A supporters would be to bullet vote, but some are likely to approve also B. The best strategy of the C supporters is to approve also B.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> This example says that approval polls may be used as a strategic tool, but I don't claim that approval polls would be worse (in approval elections) from this point of view than some other kind of polls.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Juho<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> On 31 Oct 2016, at 01:11, Michael Ossipoff <<a href="mailto:email9648742@gmail.com" target="_blank" class="">email9648742@gmail.com</a>> wrote:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> I'd like to comment on the article's strategy-suggestions. My comments will be interspersed below, demarkated above & below by a line of "&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&"<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Introduction<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Tactical voting is when voters don’t cast purely honest ballots. While voters do this to a limited extent with approval voting (link is external), the voting system still behaves remarkably well. For instance, voters can always express their honest favorite. And choosing just one candidate (bullet voting) only occurs in limited situations.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Below is how approval voting strategy is likely to play out in a variety of common scenarios.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Polling Assumption<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Since there’d be approval voting, there’d also be approval polling. It would make no sense to do polling framed in plurality when a different system is used; it would cease to be informative.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Utility Assumption for Hypotheticals<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> In these cases, let’s assume you hate Candidate Awful, are okay with Candidate Better, and love Candidate Classy. Let’s give them honest utility values (we’re rating them on a 0-10 scale):<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Awful: 0<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Better: 6<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Classy: 10<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> {Classy, Better} is a top-set, for you.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> You should approve both.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Polling Assumption<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Since there’d be approval voting, there’d also be approval polling. It would make no sense to do polling framed in plurality when a different system is used; it would cease to be informative.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> I don't agree. Either Brams or Fishburn or both wrote a paper suggesting an Approval-poll to provide tactical informaton. But such information could only come from a poll that asked people to indicate their favorite, or better-yet,their merit-ranking.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> The 2nd election, the binding one, is, by assumption, intended to benefit from the information from the first poll. But the 1st poll, if by Approval, is either 0-info, or has ulnreliable, guessed, predictive information. Then why would it indicate winnability in the 2nd vote?<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Approval Voting Example #1<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> If approval polls:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Awful: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Better: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Classy: 30%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> You want to vote for Better and Classy here. <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Yes.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> You vote for Better because you want Better to beat Awful. Classy doesn’t have a shot, but you vote for her anyway to show your support and give her ideas more legitimacy.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Approval Voting Example #2<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> If approval polls:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Awful: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Better: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Classy: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> You still vote for Better and Classy. <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Yes.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> You don’t vote for Classy alone because you have a strong preference for Better against Awful. By only voting for Better or Classy, you risk Awful winning against both of them.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Approval Voting Example #3<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> If approval polls:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Awful: 30%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Better: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Classy: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> You actually only vote for Classy here. <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> I disagree.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> {Classy, Better} is your top-set. Electing from that set matters more than the matter of _which_ of is members wins.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> In fact, Awful's win-probability is 60% as great as those of Better & Classy. You don't want to take that chance of Awful outpolling Classy. So you approve your top-set.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> When Awful is enough out of the race, you can narrow your sights against Better and show your support for Classy.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> But Awful isn't fully out of the race.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> When exactly do you only vote for Classy? It depends on how far out of the competition Better is. And it depends on how much you dislike Better along with how likable Better is compared to Awful. If Awful and Better are similarly unlikable (you’re indifferent to which one wins), a voter may be more inclined to vote for Classy alone when she is closer to winning.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Of course. That's why you wouldn't approve Hillary if we were holding the November 2016 election by Approval.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Approval Voting Example #4<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> If approval polls:<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Awful: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Better: 30%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Classy: 50%<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Again, your only vote is for Classy here. <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Disagree.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Awful has a 50% chance of outpolling Classy, and, even if Better's win-probability is slightly less than that of Awful & Classy, you should still approve (only) your entire top-set, which is {Classy, Better}.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> It’s not Better that’s giving competition to Awful anymore; it’s Classy competing against Awful. Whether you include Better in the vote would depend on how much you actually supported Better's views. Like in the first example where Classy had 30% and was a token vote, support for Better in this case is also a token vote because it likely won’t change the outcome. So, if you wanted to give support for Better because of some view he had that you liked, then you could get away with supporting him and Classy.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> [...]<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Conclusion<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> These examples remove the argument that approval voting regresses to plurality voting (via bullet voting). <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Of course.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> There are numerous scenarios (as shown above) when bullet voting simply makes no strategic sense. But notice that when you do only vote for one candidate, it’s done in a way that’s not damaging to the outcome. Also, factoring in who is likely to win is something we do anyway when considering what to do under plurality voting. But with approval voting, we just have more options on what we can do with that information. Also note that it was always to your advantage to vote your favorite. That will ALWAYS be true with approval voting.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Disregard who you think is likely to win. Nearly everyone's "information" about that comes from disinformational, wealthy-agenda media, and should be completely disregarded.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Though honest Internet polls give us a hint about who's the CWs (Jill Stein), for nearly everyone, it's a 0-info election. Anyway, as i've mentioned elsewhere, in our distorted electoral-system, voters who want something better instead of the Republocrat status-quo have a top-set & a bottom-set. When you do, you should approve (only) your top-set.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Also, when there are more candidates, there are more variations on what to do. Though the concepts are the same. Expectantly, with more candidates, voters will also approve of more candidates on average. There may also be cross-support from multiple independents/third parties that share certain views.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Yes. <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Finally, even with “tactical” voting, approval voting will nearly always choose the candidate that can beat everyone in a head-to-head race. This is called a Condorcet winner. Approval voting does not achieve this flawlessly, but it does an excellent job nonetheless. It is also argued that when approval voting doesn’t select the Condorcet winner, it does so for good reason.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Yes. <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> &&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&&<wbr class="">&&&&&&&&&&<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> More on this topic here.<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Topic: <br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Tactical Voting<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> ----<br class="">
>>>>>>>>>> Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="http://electorama.com/em" target="_blank" class="">http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>>>> ----<br class="">
>>>>>>>>> Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="http://electorama.com/em" target="_blank" class="">http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br class="">
>>>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>>> ----<br class="">
>>>>>>> Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="http://electorama.com/em" target="_blank" class="">http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br class="">
>>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>>><br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>>> ----<br class="">
>>>>> Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="http://electorama.com/em" target="_blank" class="">http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br class="">
>>>>><br class="">
>>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>><br class="">
>>> ----<br class="">
>>> Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="http://electorama.com/em" target="_blank" class="">http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br class="">
>>><br class="">
><br class="">
><br class="">
> ----<br class="">
> Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href="http://electorama.com/em" target="_blank" class="">http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info<br class="">
><br class="">
</p>
</div></div></blockquote></div><br class=""></div>
</div></blockquote></div><br class=""></body></html>