<br><div class="gmail_quote"><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex;"><div class="gmail_quote"><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex">
<div class="gmail_quote"><div>
strategic incentives, </div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div><div>2. Whether one ranks a second or third choice could only back fire if there was a close race between your first choice and one of your other choices for being the third place candidate in the first stage. This isn't likely and even then, it's safe to say that the third/fourth place candidate in the first stage has a less than 1/3rd chance to be the winner in the second stage. </div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div><div>You are arguing that the costs of adding preferences are probably nil. But essentially the same argument applies to the benefits.</div><div><br></div><div><br></div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex;">
<div class="gmail_quote">
<div><br></div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex"><div class="gmail_quote"><div>and LNH. </div></div></blockquote><div>3. It's no longer 100%, but it's up there. Similarly, there'd still be a chance of non-monotonicity, but it'd be relatively low and thereby unlikely enough not to affect voters strategies dysfunctionally. </div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div><div>LNH matters most in a Burlington-like scenario, where it arguably kept the Republican from winning --- the plurality winner and Condorcet loser among the three frontrunners there. That is, by reassuring the Democrats that it couldn't hurt them to second-rank the Progressive, it prevented a chicken dilemma. This is exactly the situation when the almost-LNH of your system breaks down. </div>
<div><br></div><div>(I just realized that my "2" and "3" in this list in my prior message were actually the same reason.)</div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex;">
<div class="gmail_quote"><div class="im"><div>...</div></div><div>I would likewise be willing to wager a good deal that the diff between circa 90% LNH and 100% LNH is not a good deal-killer, especially for a bigger election with potentially a large number of candidates. </div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div><div>See above.</div><div> </div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex;"><div class="gmail_quote"><div class="im">
<blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex"><div class="gmail_quote"><div><div> </div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex">
<div class="gmail_quote">
<div><br></div><div>Maybe they too are biased in favor of simplicity?? </div><div>And I don't think the Condorcet criterion is <i>that important</i>, as I think in political elections, our options are inherently fuzzy options and so all of our rankings are prone to be ad hoc. </div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div></div><div>Criterion-based arguments might be brittle in the face of noisy input data. BR-based arguments, including those which attempt to account for strategic incentives, are not. In other words: arguing that options are fuzzy does not give a license to ignore the flaws in your proposal.</div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div></div><div>dlw: aye, and I do not rely on that arg alone. </div><div><br></div><div>For BR-based args, some of my key args I rely on are: the over-reliance on cardinal utility assumptions and the import of the number of effective candidates in an election. I believe based on my understanding of how BR works that the fewer candidates you got in a BR model that the less extreme are the diffs between AV and IRV. IMO, 7 candidates is too much for an election model, because there really only tend to be at most 4 serious candidates in most single-winner elections. It's because of the cost of campaigning is too high relative to the chance of reward when too many serious candidates are in the mix...</div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div><div>Interesting point. I hadn't thought of this as being a pro-IRV (or at least, anti-anti-IRV) argument, but now I see what you're saying.</div><div> </div><blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex;">
<div class="gmail_quote"><div class="im">
<blockquote class="gmail_quote" style="margin:0 0 0 .8ex;border-left:1px #ccc solid;padding-left:1ex"><div class="gmail_quote">
<div><br></div><font color="#888888"><div>Jameson</div></font><div><br></div><div>ps. While I spend a lot more words on where I disagree with you, you seem like a smart person and I bet I agree with you >> 80%.</div>
</div></blockquote><div><br></div></div><div>since you likewise are a smart and sincere person, I'd bet I can get that to be >>90% in a week or so...</div><div></div></div></blockquote></div><div><br></div><div>
Admirable response. I'd have to agree... but of course, I'd guess that >2/3 of that will be <i>me</i> convincing <i>you</i>. :)</div><div><br></div><div>Jameson</div>