[EM] proportional list

Ross Hyman rossahyman at gmail.com
Tue Jun 24 14:37:23 PDT 2025


Hi Kristofer,

You are correct. The Aziz top-down method, the Phragmen bottom up
method, and the Phragmen top down method are based on
Jefferson/D'Hondt and share its properties of Droop proportionality
and coherence. There are differences in which candidates they elect,
based on the fact that the Phragmen methods can elect from "imperfect"
solid coalitions.

You are also correct that the main reason house monotonic lists are
required to be produced are for proportional representation elections.
I can think of three situations where they would be useful: 1) a
party's production of a closed list that voters vote on in the
election, 2) a party's production of a list that voters can choose to
select instead of ranking candidates in and STV election, 3) an
organization's production of a list that it promotes to voters in an
STV election.

I looked and could not find any definitive examples of a party or
organization creating a proportional list through a ranked-candidate
election of its members.

The examples I quoted in the paper, from Voting Matters, were the
closest I could find. It is unclear from those papers if the proposed
elections described in those papers were ever held.

I would be interested to learn examples of how parties and
organizations create their proportional lists.

Best,
Ross





On Tue, Jun 24, 2025 at 1:28 PM Kristofer Munsterhjelm
<km-elmet at munsterhjelm.no> wrote:
>
> On 2025-06-23 19:05, Ross Hyman via Election-Methods wrote:
> > Dear all,
> > I would like to draw your attention to a pre-print I have uploaded to arxiv.
> > https://arxiv.org/abs/2506.12318
> > A House Monotone, Coherent, and Droop Proportional Ranked Candidate
> > Voting Method
> > Ross Hyman
> > Subjects: Theoretical Economics (econ.TH)
> > A Ranked candidate voting method based on Phragmen's procedure is
> > described that can be used to produce a top-down proportional
> > candidate list. The method complies with the Droop proportionality
> > criterion satisfied by Single Transferable Vote. It also complies with
> > house monotonicity and coherence, which are the ranked-candidate
> > analogs of the divisor methods properties of always avoiding the
> > Alabama and New State paradoxes. The highest ranked candidate in the
> > list is the Instant Runoff winner, which is in at least one Droop
> > proportional set of N winners for all N.
>
> As I understood it from my first glance, the main differences between
> your method and Aziz's methods are
>         - vs bottom-up: yours is top-down and thus elects the same top
> candidate as the base method (QPQ/IRV).
>         - vs top-down: yours doesn't need to go through every solid coalition.
>
> Is that correct, or did I miss some other properties?
>
> > If I were to rewrite the paper for an audience interested primarily in
> > single-winner elections. I would emphasise the following things:
> >
> > A Droop proportional list has the property that the top N candidates
> > in the list, for any N, satisfy the Droop proportionality criterion
> > for N winners.
> >
> > A Droop proportional list is a candidate list in which independence of
> > irrelevant alternatives is not a desirable election criterion. For
> > proportionally to be complied with, the weight of a ballot's input in
> > deciding the relative ordering of candidates A and B should depend on
> > the placement of other candidates on the ballot, since these other
> > candidates can be elected to a high position on the list and reduce
> > the weight of the ballot for deciding lower positions.
> >
> > In general, the Condorcet winner cannot always be at the top of a
> > proportional list.  It is easy to devise ballot sets where two
> > candidates each have more than a third of the vote, so they must be in
> > the top two positions, and neither is the Condorcet winner.
> >
> > The Instant Runoff winner can always be at the top of a proportional
> > list. There will always be a Droop proportional compliant set of N
> > winners, for any N, that includes the IRV winner. I prove this in the
> > paper. I also suggest in the paper that this property of the IRV
> > winner is a way to give quantitative meaning to the term "core
> > support."
>
> This is why I think house monotonicity comes with a cost. In a
> left-center-right situation like the one you described, you can either
> have center squeeze (if your proportional ordering is, say, Left > Right
>  > Center), or you can have disproportionality (Center > Right > Left).
>
> So IMHO, for a general multiwinner method, unless there's a particular
> reason, house monotonicity is not desirable. Party lists require house
> monotonicity so you have no choice there, but with a setting like STV,
> there shouldn't be any reason to require house monotonicity.
>
> (It would be interesting to find out how parties solve this problem in
> countries with party list. No matter how the party draws up the list,
> those who do so are faced with the same trade-off since the party list
> format forces house monotonicity.)
>
> -km


More information about the Election-Methods mailing list