[EM] Exact spatial model probabilities?

Forest Simmons forest.simmons21 at gmail.com
Fri Jan 21 21:53:14 PST 2022


These are fantastic questions.

The spherical geometry makes sense for Universal Domain methods because, as
Saari pointed out in his Geometry of Voting, the natural distance between
two permutations is the number of transpositions it takes to convert one
into the other... the Kemeny distance.

There are 12 permutations of three candidates ... which arrange themselves
naturally on the face of a clock.  Any "Gray Code" where successive
permutations differ by only one transposition will match the twelve hours
with the twelve permutations:

For example, ABC, ACB, CAB, CBA, BCA, BAC, and back to  ABC. Each
permutation will be diametrically opposite to its reverse order.

For permutations of four candidates you get 24 points on the surface of a
sphere.

Each permutation is adjacent to three others. For example, ABCD is next to
BACD, ACBD, and ABDC. When you arrange all 24 of these permutations
symmetrically on the surface of a sphere, so that the distance between any
two adjacent permutations is the same, you will find that reversed
permutations are polar opposites.

It's harder to visualize the arrangement of the 120 permutations of five
symbols, but topologically they  reside symmetrically on the surface of a
4-dimensional ball. The surface of a four dimensional compact manifold is
in general a three dimensional manifold, in this case a 3-sphere, just as
the surface of a 3-dimensional ball is an ordinary 2-dimensional sphere ...
2D manifolds have area, while 3D manifolds have volume. A circle, the
boundary of a disc, is a "1-sphere" because it has length, namely its
circumference.

General Relativity (without black holes or worm holes) models the Big Bang
as a four dimensional space-time manifold whose temporal cross sections are
3-spheres ... precisely the kind of spheres on which the 120 distinct
complete rankings of five candidates must be arranged if you require
adjacent rankings to be the same distance apart.

So the space of permutations of n symbols consists of n factorial points
distributed evenly on the boundary of an (n-1) dimensional ball. A
Euclidean ball of radius R consists of all vectors v having L_2 norms ||v||
less than or equal to R.The set where equality holds is its boundary. If
the vector space has a basis of n vectors, the ball of radius R will be n
dimensional, and its boundary will be (n-1) dimensional.

These high dimensional vector spaces are ubiquitous in science, especially
in quantum mechanics and other applications of partial differential
equations ... the general mathematical setting being "Functional Analysis."

So Saari had the right idea topologically, but not metrically ...the same
topological space can have many different metrics that yield the same
topology, and the Kemeny metric is not quite right; by making all adjacent
permutations the exact same distance apart, the Kemeny metric introduces
clone dependence into methods based on it ... most notably the Kemeny-Young
method, and Borda as related to Saari's geometry of voting.

In my de-cloned Kemeny-Young posts, I have shown how to modify the Kemeny
metric to make it respect the natural clustering of clone sets, while
preserving the natural Kemeny generated topology.

Topology is all about local stretching and shrinking without ripping apart
or smashing together either the natural proximities or the large scale
connections.

Now we start to see the difficulty of trying to work within Universal
Domain rules: UD requires ballots that are permutations of the candidates,
so if we identify voters with their ballots, voters are distributed on
spheres. But issue spaces are products of line segments, like rectangles,
blocks, etc.

If there are two issues, then issue space is a rectangle. If there are four
candidates, then ballot space is a two dimensional sphere, so according to
UD rules, that only allow voter influence through their ballot rankings,
there is a topological mismatch of voter/ballot space and issue space.

For example, the Borsuk-Ulam theorem shows that any continuous map from an
n-sphere into a rectangle (or any other lower dimensional product of
intervals) must have a pair of polar opposite points that get mapped to the
same point; i.e. this requires that two polar opposite rankings correspond
to the exact same point in issue space.

That's one reason I take Universal Domain rules with a grain of salt, and
feel free to supplement rankings with ratings, approval cutoffs, etc.

I know that's not any help with your main question, but it may give some
insight into Durand's spherical distribution suggestion.


I'll try to give a practical suggestion next time!


El vie., 21 de ene. de 2022 7:02 a. m., Kristofer Munsterhjelm <
km_elmet at t-online.de> escribió:

> My minimum-manipulability optimization system can find exact
> probabilities that a voter will vote according to a particular ranking,
> under impartial culture.
>
> It's easy to approximately find such probabilities for spatial models as
> well by just creating an instance and randomly placing voters on it to
> determine what they vote, and hence in the limit of number of trials
> going to infinity, get the probability.
>
> But I was wondering, is it possible to do so exactly? Let's say that in
> a spatial model, first c candidates are placed uniformly at random in an
> unit d-cube. Then voters are also placed uniformly at random in this
> cube and they prefer candidates closer to them to candidates further away.
>
> Now I would suppose that the probability that a voter votes A first is
> equal to the volume of the Voronoi cell that belongs to A. (And the
> probability that a voter will vote A>B>C is the volume of the
> intersection of the closest-neighbor Voronoi cell for A with the
> second-closest-neighbor for B and the third-closest-neighbor for C.)
>
> Well, that eliminates one source of randomness -- assuming I can exactly
> calculate the vertices of these regions. But there's still the second
> source in the randomness of the candidates. Do you know of any calculus
> tricks to get the probabilities over every possible candidate position,
> or is this simply too hairy?
>
> One benefit of the spatial model over impartial culture is that it's
> much more clear how one may assign utilities to each ranking, so the
> optimization system could also be used to investigate tradeoffs between
> VSE and manipulability. (Durand suggested sampling on a sphere for
> associating utilities with impartial culture, but I haven't read the
> suggestion in detail. https://arxiv.org/pdf/1511.01303.pdf)
>
> -km
> ----
> Election-Methods mailing list - see https://electorama.com/em for list
> info
>
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20220121/f63dfa25/attachment.html>


More information about the Election-Methods mailing list