[EM] Example with tie in Schulze method but not in IRV (small correction)

Luděk Belán LudekBelan at seznam.cz
Sun Sep 25 13:12:52 PDT 2016


Thank you all for your helpful responses. It will take me some time study 
them :-).



Luděk Belán








---------- Původní zpráva ----------
Od: Juho Laatu <juho.laatu at gmail.com>
Komu: EM <election-methods at lists.electorama.com>
Datum: 16. 9. 2016 9:26:03
Předmět: Re: [EM] Example with tie in Schulze method but not in IRV (small 
correction)

"

"
On 16 Sep 2016, at 03:28, Forest Simmons <fsimmons at pcc.edu
(mailto:fsimmons at pcc.edu)> wrote:












Something else interesting about this example:



First write out the five individual ballots




 BCA


 BCA

 CAB

 ABC

 ACB


In the spirit of Dodgson find which (if any) simple preference reversal(s) 
will produce a ballot set with a (ballot) Condorcet Winner:


Candidate A becomes a CW if any of the three CA pairs is reversed.

Candidate B becomes the CW  if either of the two AB pairs is reversed.

Candidate C becomes the CW if any of the three BC pairs is reversed.



No other single reversal will create a CW, i.e. neither simple reversal in 
the last ballot ACB will create a CW.  However, in that ballot if the AC 
pair is reversed, then candidate C becomes the beat-path (and Borda) winner.
  And if the CB pair is reversed, then candidate B becomes the beat-path 
(and Borda) winner.



So the appropriate lottery to break the Dodgson tie is


   37.5%A+ 25%B+37.5%C



And the appropriate lottery for breaking either the beat-path or Borda tie 
is


   30%A + 30%B + 40%C




[all under the assumption that a random tie breaker is desired]









Also, it is interesting that the Dodgson lottery expectation is preferred 
over the sure A option by the first three ballots, assuming equally spaced 
utilities.



Sure candidate B is preferred over the Dodgson lottery on the first two 
ballots, liked less on the two ballots where it is ranked bottom, and 
equally on the other ballot. (so a tie)



Candidate C is preferred over the Dodgson lottery on the first three 
ballots, but not on the other two.



One might also consider the Random Ballot ("benchmark") lottery as a tie 
breaker:



40%A + 40%B + 20%C








"



This one made me think of also other alternatives. Picking just one of the 
voters to make the decision sounds a bit "random". How about breaking the 
tie by removing one vote at a time until there is a Condorcet winner? This 
is in a way a softer version of the Random Ballot method. Eventually there 
would be only one vote left (if you will not et a Condorcet winner before 
that), and this softened method reduces to a hard Random Ballot method.




Another (completely different) classical approach to breaking ties would be 
to add votes until there is a Condorcet winner. The candidate who needs the 
smallest number of additions will win. This approach is fair and neutral in 
the sense that we don't eliminate any voter opinions but just introduce 
additional imaginary ones. The problem with this approach is that it brings 
us close to the infamous(?) Minmax margins (MMM) method :-) . This one has 
also the problem that it is not a complete tie solver since ties are still 
possible, so we may need to complement this by adding one more tie breaking 
mechanism on top of it. The random ballot and random ballot elimination 
approaches could be used as final tie breakers. Or if you want to have a 
probability lottery, then maybe give additional votes to each candidate in 
random order until one of them can reaches the Condorcet winner level 
(without considering the votes that others have already collected). This 
would mean probability in proportion to the needed additional votes to 
become a Condorcet winner. In the example above this would be 33.3%A + 33.3%
B + 33.3%C. Actually this (final tie breaker for MMM) would always be a 
lottery with equal weights (between those candidates that need the least 
number of additional votes).




But what if we would jump to the lottery approach without the intermediate 
(MMM) phase of declaring the candidate that needs the least additional votes
as the winner. In this case we would just start casting random votes to the 
candidates whenever there is no Condorcet winner, until one of them would 
reach the required additional votes limit (without considering how many 
additional votes the others have so far received). This approach might have 
some beneficial impact on the strategies. It might not pay off to try to 
bury some candidate under an unwanted candidate since the probability of 
that candidate winning would rise. I can't tell yet how this variant would 
relate to the other lottery based approaches. Ffs to me.




BR, Juho




"










If we use the "Toby" transform to convert the ballots to weighted sums of 
approval ballots, and then use random approval, we get



[31(A+B)+28C]/90, which is very close to "random candidate"  (A+B+C)/3 .





Whom would the US Supreme Court choose?  



Answer: the one most connected to wealth and power.



Best Wishes,



Forest























On Thu, Sep 15, 2016 at 12:52 AM, C.Benham <cbenham at adam.com.au
(mailto:cbenham at adam.com.au)> wrote:
" 


In defining Forest's algorithm I wrote:

"  "For as long as it is possible, keep adding to the chain the most 
approved candidate that pairwise beats the last candidate added."" 
The "pairwise beats" is wrong. It should be  ' covers'.

Also I  omitted  the detail in the Margins-Sort algorithm of what to do when
score gaps between pairwise out-of-order candidates are the same.  

These mistakes are fixed in text below.

Chris Benham


On 9/15/2016 3:25 AM, C.Benham wrote:

" 
Luděk,

One of the methods I like for public elections is a Condorcet-IRV hybrid 
(the simplest of several) that has been dubbed "Benham".

Voters strictly rank from the top however many candidates they wish. If a 
Condorcet winner exists, he/she wins. Otherwise continue
with IRV, checking before each elimination for a CW among remaining 
candidates and electing the first one to appear.

A few others I like use "approval" information, interpreting above-bottom 
ranking as approval  (unless the ballot rules allow/invite
voters to explicitly specify an approval threshold in their rankings). 

One of these methods that works here is Approval Margins Sort:  Line up the 
candidates in order of approval from highest to lowest
as the first tentative ordering of the candidates (with the Approval winner 
highest in the order).  Look for adjacent pairs of candidates
where the candidate lower in the order pairwise beats the one higher in the 
order. If there are none then the order is confirmed and
candidate highest in the order wins.

If there are adjacent pairs of candidate who are "out of pairwise order", 
flip the order of the one (of those pairs) with the smallest approval-score 
gap.
If among the out-of-pairwise-order adjacent pairs there is gap-size tie, 
flip the order of lowest ordered pair.

Repeat until each candidate not bottom in the order pairwise beats the 
candidate just below it.  Then elect the highest-ordered candidate.

http://wiki.electorama.com/ wiki/Approval_Sorted_Margins
(http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Approval_Sorted_Margins)


1: A>B
2: B>C
1: C>A
1: C>A

Approval Scores:  C4 >  A3 = B3

Here B and A have the same approval scores but are out of order pairwise, so
the next tentative order is  C > A > B.  Now no adjacent
pair of candidates (C>A or  A>B) is out of pairwise  order so that order is 
final and C wins.

Another one of the methods I like for public office is  Smith//Approval: 
Elect the most approved member of the Smith set.  The "Smith
set" is the smallest set of candidates that pairwise-beat all (if any) of 
the candidates outside the set.

Here all the candidates are in the Smith set, and the most approved of them 
is C, so again C wins.

Something a bit more elegant that might give a different result in a 
complicated example with more than 3 candidates in the Smith set
is a suggestion of Forrest Simmons:  Construct a "chain" of candidates thus:
begin with the most approved candidate. If no candidate
"covers" this candidate A (i.e. pairwise beats A and also pairwise beats 
every candidate that A pairwise beats and doesn't pairwise lose
to any candidate A pairwise ties with) then A wins. Otherwise add to the 
chain the most approved candidate that covers A.  For as long
as it is possible, keep adding to the chain the most approved candidate that
covers the last candidate added. When no new candidate
can be added, elect the last added candidate.

In this example all the voters have submitted a full ranking, so maybe they 
(and/or you) think that interpreting above-bottom ranking as
approval is arbitrary and too much focused on the bottoms of the ballots. 

In that case a possible alternative is Borda Margins-Sort Elimination:  
Using Borda scores (on each ballot each candidate gets a point-score
equal to the number of candidates ranked below it. Candidates ranked the 
same should perhaps be handled in a away that meets "Symmetric
Completion", so that say a  "A=B > C"  ballot should give 1.5 points each to
A and B and zero points to C.) instead of Approval scores, order
the candidates as in Approval-Margins Sort.  

Then eliminate the lowest ordered candidate, recalculate new Borda scores 
without the eliminated candidate. Repeat until the last remaining 3 
candidates
are finally ordered and then elect the one highest in that order.

In your example the candidates'  Borda scores are the same (5), so here this
method is also a tie.

Chris Benham



On 9/14/2016 5:27 PM, Luděk Belán wrote:

"Chris, 
thank you for confirmation. Do you know any variant of Schulze method (or of
other Condorcet method) to determine the winner in this example?

Thank you.




Luděk Belán






---------- Původní zpráva ----------
Od: C.Benham <cbenham at adam.com.au>(mailto:cbenham at adam.com.au)
Komu: election-methods at lists. electorama.com
(mailto:election-methods at lists.electorama.com)
Datum: 12. 9. 2016 18:36:36
Předmět: Re: [EM] Example with tie in Schulze method but not in IRV

"Luděk,

Yes, you are right.


Chris Benham



On 9/12/2016 7:47 PM, Luděk Belán wrote:
> Dear all,
>
> excuse my bad English.
>
> Example for discusion:
> Candidates: A, B, C
> Ballots (count: order):
> 1: A>B>C
> 2: B>C>A
> 1: C>A>B
> 1: A>C>B
>
> In Instant Runoff Voting wins candidate A, but in Schulze method in my 
opinion is result tie.
> It's true, please?
>
> Best regards
>
> Luděk Belán
> ----
> Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em
(http://electorama.com/em) for list info
>
>
> -----
> No virus found in this message.
> Checked by AVG - www.avg.com(http://www.avg.com/)
> Version: 2016.0.7752 / Virus Database: 4649/13000 - Release Date: 09/11/16


----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em
(http://electorama.com/em) for list info" 

No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com(http://www.avg.com/)
Version: 2016.0.7797 / Virus Database: 4656/13012 - Release Date: 09/13/16
"





----
Election-Methods mailing list - see <a href='http://electorama.com/em'>http://electorama.com/em</a> for list info




No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com(http://www.avg.com/)
Version: 2016.0.7797 / Virus Database: 4656/13016 - Release Date: 09/14/16
"



"


----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em
(http://electorama.com/em) for list info

"


----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info"
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20160925/ce7fcc2d/attachment-0001.htm>


More information about the Election-Methods mailing list