[EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 106, Issue 2
Forest Simmons
fsimmons at pcc.edu
Thu Apr 4 16:50:52 PDT 2013
Kris,
Optimal MJ strategy is still approval strategy. You can instruct the
voters to make absolute choices, but you cannot enforce it. Their
willingness to abide by the instructions is purely psychological. The same
psychology will work, only better for Consensus Threshold Approval.
Forest
On Thu, Apr 4, 2013 at 2:02 AM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm <km_elmet at lavabit.com
> wrote:
> On 04/04/2013 02:40 AM, Forest Simmons wrote:
>
>>
>>
>> On Wed, Apr 3, 2013 at 12:07 AM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm
>> <km_elmet at lavabit.com <mailto:km_elmet at lavabit.com>> wrote:
>>
>>
> Perhaps there's some value in making methods that appeal to the
>> right sentiment, even if one has to trade off "objective" qualities
>> (like BR, strategy resistance or criterion compliance) to get there.
>> The trouble is that we can't quantify this, nor how much of
>> sentiment-appeal makes up for deficiencies elsewhere, at least not
>> without performing costly experiments.
>>
>>
>> If I am not mistaken, both methods (Chiastic and this one) are
>> strategically equivalent to Approval from a game theoretic point of
>> view. But psychologically they are quite different. I think that this
>> new version is much less likely to elicit approval style responses (at
>> the extremes) than ordinary Range voting for example, or even the median
>> method with J in the title (I can't think of it at the moment).
>>
>>
> I found a quite broad reduction for ratings-type methods. I posted it when
> I did, but I'll repeat it.
>
> Say you have a rated ballot set, and candidate C's set of scores is
> represented by the vector s_C (first element in the vector is the first
> voter's rating of the candidate, and so on), then:
>
> - if each candidate gets a meta-score, call it m_C, from some function
> f(s_C),
> - the candidate with the highest meta-score wins,
> - and f(s_C) is monotone in the sense that increasing a rating in s_C
> never makes f(s_C) evaluate to a lower value than before, and decreasing a
> rating in s_C never makes f(s_C) evaluate to a higher value than before,
>
> - then Approval strategy is optimal.
>
> The reason is that if a voter likes a candidate X, he can never be worse
> off by not giving X a higher score; and if he dislikes X, he can never be
> worse off by not giving X a lower score. Thus the scores migrate to the
> Approval extremes.
>
> And unless I'm missing something, both the chiastic method and your method
> fulfill the properties above.
>
> There's a caveat: the "optimality" might be of a form where it never hurts
> you to go to an extreme, but it doesn't hurt not to either. To eliminate
> that kind of equilibrium, one would have to replace the monotonicity
> property with something stronger.
>
> -
>
> As for the median method, you're probably thinking of Majority Judgement.
> As long as the voters act in the way B&L say they should do, and judge
> candidates to absolute grades rather than comparing the candidates to each
> other, it avoids Approval reduction. B&L use evidence from France to argue
> that enough voters judge to absolute grades that it effectively works this
> way. Maybe your method would also do so, but then it would have to be
> phrased in terms of grades rather than numbers.
>
> I think that Range encourages rating at the extremes, though it doesn't
> seem to always do so. Web sites lend evidence to both sides: IMDB used (and
> uses) Range for the movie ratings, while Youtube switched from ratings to
> Approval-style up-and-down voting. IMDB does some filtering on the votes,
> though, so perhaps that's what is keeping it from reducing to approval. In
> any case, it shouldn't be hard to make a method that's more resistant than
> bare Range in that respect.
>
>
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20130404/1d91c9e8/attachment-0002.htm>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list