[EM] An interesting real election
Andrew Myers
andru at cs.cornell.edu
Sun Jan 30 23:50:47 PST 2011
Yes, notice that if someone now votes 2 > 1 > 6, the Schulze method
picks 1 over 2, which is the opposite of what the new voter wanted.
But I'm not really trying to criticize the Schulze method here --
perhaps the most salient thing is how rarely situations like this come
up in Condorcet voting.
-- Andrew
On 7/22/64 2:59 PM, Aaron Armitage wrote:
> 1 has a path to 6 at least as strong as 6's path to 1, namely 1>3>6, at
> 15-11 and 14-11. It
> seems a little odd, to me at least, that 6's path to 1 should benefit 2
> but not 6 itself.
> Starting from the top seems the only way of ensuring that the path that
> orders the two
> candidates relative to each other is the one which actually contributes
> to the final outcome.
>
> --- On *Sat, 1/29/11, Andrew Myers /<andru at cs.cornell.edu>/* wrote:
>
>
> From: Andrew Myers <andru at cs.cornell.edu>
> Subject: [EM] An interesting real election
> To: "Election Methods Mailing List" <election-methods at electorama.com>
> Date: Saturday, January 29, 2011, 4:40 PM
>
> Here is an unusual case from a real poll run recently by a group
> using CIVS. Usually there is a Condorcet winner, but not this time.
> Who should win?
>
> Ranked pairs says #1, and ranks the six choices as shown. It only
> has to reverse one preference. Schulze says #2, because it beats #6
> by 15-11, and #6 beats #1 by 14-13. So #2 has a 14-13 beatpath vs.
> #1. Hill's method ("Condorcet-IRV") picks #6 as the winner.
>
> -- Andrew
>
> 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6.
> 1.
> - 13 15 17 16 13
> 2.
> 9 - 13 14 17 15
> 3. 11 11 - 13 15 14
> 4.
> 9 10 10 - 14 13
> 5.
> 11 10 9 10 - 13
> 6.
> 14 11 11 13 10 -
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list