[EM] Fair and Democratic versus Majority Rules
fsimmons at pcc.edu
fsimmons at pcc.edu
Wed Nov 17 17:34:37 PST 2010
Kristofer,
Stochastic methods should only be used in situations where all of the alternatives qualify for the job.
It should not be used for screening the candidates.
Forest
----- Original Message -----
From: Kristofer Munsterhjelm
Date: Wednesday, November 17, 2010 4:35 am
Subject: Re: [EM] Fair and Democratic versus Majority Rules
To: fsimmons at pcc.edu
Cc: election-methods at lists.electorama.com
> fsimmons at pcc.edu wrote:
> > How did this thread get side tracked to Proportional Representation?
> >
> > Proportional Representation only works for multi-winner elections.
> >
> > Of course, everybody knows that PR is the way to go in multi-
> winner elections.
> > And why is that? Because it solves the tyranny of the
> majority problem in that
> > setting.
> >
> > So why cannot we see that this same problem exists in single
> winner elections? I
> > suggest that the analogous remedy in the single winner setting
> is proportional
> > probability. The simplest method that accomplishes this is
> random ballot. But,
> > as I suggested, there are better stochastic methods that yield
> probability> distributions with less entropy while still solving
> the tyranny of the majority
> > problem..
>
> An assembly picked by PR stabilizes itself because the
> differently
> positioned candidates balance each other out and actually meet
> and
> discuss. If the assembly rules have supermajority rules, that
> may also
> make it more likely to reach a consensus rather than oscillating
> between
> extreme positions.
>
> On the other hand, in a single-winner election, there is only
> one
> winner. That winner usually won't have an "inner assembly" to
> balance
> himself. Thus, I think that the reaction against
> nondeterministic
> methods arise from the thought that if we can't be sure who will
> win,
> the candidate who wins might win simply by the luck of the draw
> and be
> unsuitable - and then we're stuck with him without other council
> members
> to moderate him.
>
> Abd's 10% example is an example of this. If 10% think
> [disastrous
> policy] is really good and votes accordingly, then by using
> Random
> Ballot, you'd get that disastrous policy 10% of the time. While
> Random
> Ballot may find a brilliant policy that only 10% knows of, it
> can't
> discern between that and a horrible policy that (rightly) no
> more than
> 10% support, and the loss from the latter would more than
> outweigh the
> gain from the former.
>
> Or so one would argue.
>
> In a low-entropy method, as far as I understand it, there still
> has to
> be a random component that encourages the voters to find a
> compromise.
> If the fallback component is too close to a deterministic
> method, then
> the majority won't care to try and find a consensus because
> they'll
> benefit more from the fallback. On the other hand, if it's too
> random,
> it could be bad indeed if the different groups truly can't find
> a
> compromise.
>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list