[Election-Methods] Determining representativeness of multiwinner methods
Kristofer Munsterhjelm
km-elmet at broadpark.no
Fri Jun 20 15:09:03 PDT 2008
Hello all,
(says the newcomer.)
I think I have found a metric for comparing multiwinner systems, at
least as these pertain to proportional representation, when all votes
are honest.
The advantage of the metric is that, if what it measures is desirable,
it gives an idea of how good the system performs - how representative it
is - and thus its best case performance. In contrast, criterion failure
shows how bad a system can get in the worst case.
The broad idea is this: The most proportional assembly is the one which
reflects the population on all issues. In other words, if a fraction p
of the population is of a certain position on a binary opinion, it is
better (ceteris paribus) for a council to have, of that opinion, a
fraction close to p than one far away from it.
Thus we could make a simulation. First, set that there are n binary
issues. Each of the voters then have an issue profile which consists of
n booleans. Set these randomly with different biases for each issue (so
that, for instance, on the first issue, 70% may hold the "true"
position, while on another, only 23% do).
Counting the proportion that hold the true-position for each issue gives
the popular issue profile. In general, the issue profile of a certain
subset takes the form of n numbers (for n issues), where each number is
equal to the proportion that holds the true-position for the issue in
question.
Then a perfectly representative assembly has an issue profile that is
equal to the issue profile of the people. So now we have a measure of
how well the assembly or council represents the people: the more its
issue profile differs from that of the people, the less representative
it is.
However, this presents a problem. How does one aggregate the difference
on each issue into a single score? Is a one-percent difference on a
single issue better than 1/n percent difference on all issues? One way
to solve this is to just settle on an aggregation measure (like
root-mean-square) and hope the results can be generalized across;
another is to use Pareto-domination as a measure instead, in saying that
councils produced by a method A is better than councils produced by a
method B to the extent that A-councils lie strictly closer to the
population profile than does B. That approach can give no information on
the cases where some issues are closer by method A and some are closer
by B (mutual nondomination).
Putting all of the pieces together, to figure out the scores, a
simulation would do something like this:
- Generate issue vectors for all of the people, and get the
popular issue profile.
- Choose a subset of the people as candidates.
- Generate ballots for each voter of all the candidates.
- For a great number of random assemblies:
- Get the issue profile of this assembly, and calculate
the similarity measure for that with regards to
the popular issue profile.
- If the similarity measure is more similar or less
similar than any random assembly we've seen so
far, update the worst (respectively best)
record.
- For each multiwinner election system:
- Feed the ballots into the system.
- Get the issue profile of the elected assembly, and
calculate the similarity measure for that with
regards to the popular issue profile.
- Normalize the similarity measure with regards to the
worst and best random councils.
- Add the normalized similarity measure to that system's
running total.
To be robust, it would do this a lot of times with various population
sizes, council sizes, and issue numbers (n). With a similarity measure,
0 would be perfect (impossible most of the time), and 1 (or infinity,
depending on the measure) be the worst possible.
The only thing remaining is to find out how to generate ballots for each
voter. A reasonable assumption is that voters are going to prefer the
candidates who agree with them on many issues to those that agree with
them on a few. For binary issues, Hamming distance works: in the simple
model, voters rank (or rate) the candidates inversely of Hamming distance.
--
I have made a program that does this. It is simple, does not use equal
ranks (randomizing preferences instead), but the results are interesting.
Worst of the lot are the majoritarian systems ported to multiwinner
systems. Those would, for a council of size k, just pick the k first in
the social order of the single-winner method. This result shouldn't be
surprising, because the straight port excludes minority opinion. Of some
curiosity, however, is that IRV does the best among those; maybe it
reflects IRV's origins as the multiwinner method STV? Or maybe noise (as
resulting from nonmonotonicity and the likes) bring it closer to the
results gained by just picking a random assembly.
Then come the vote-reweighted methods, like RRV. Vote-reweighted methods
can be generalized as: run a single-winner method, then reweight those
who voted for the winner, according to some function that does not take
the number of seats into account. Then run again, and disregarding those
that have already been elected, pick the next member as the one who is
closest to the top in the social ordering output.
Best of all were the "proper" methods implemented: STV (with Senatorial
rules) and QLTD-PR, which uses Woodall's QLTD instead of IRV as its
basis: it adds fractional votes until someone gets above the quota, then
reweights the voters who contributed to that one, basing the weighting
on the candidate's surplus.
According to the RMSE scores:
Majoritarian assemblies:
Borda: 0.871528 *Plurality: 0.256192
Antiplurality: 0.73616 Nauru-Borda: 0.599807
IRV: 0.362097 Cardinal ratings: 0.894351
Vote-reweighted assemblies:
Borda: 0.376745 *Plurality: 0.260454
Antiplurality: 0.401539 Nauru-Borda: 0.406815
RRV (k = 1.0): 0.682116 RRV (k = 0.5): 0.644339
Quota:
*STV: 0.193959 *QLTD-PR: 0.121693
QLTD-PR (rated): 0.417813
Other:
Random Cands: 0.364437
STV-QLTD Pareto dominance: QLTD: 236, STV: 237, nondomin: 674
"Plurality" is the weighted positional system of {1, 0, 0....}
applied to ranked ballots.
(* marks those that are better than a random assembly, on
average)
Some of the results may be due to artifacts in the voting pattern - the
simulator was a proof of concept, after all. I think that Plurality
benefits by that everyone votes sincerely, and that the ballots are
complete, for instance. Yet patterns emerge.
If anyone wants to experiment with the simulation program, it is here:
http://munsterhjelm.no/km/raw/pr_elect.zip . QLTD is called "Quota
Bucklin" there, as I sort of independently discovered it while trying to
make a quota-proportional form of Bucklin.
--
On a second thought, it shouldn't be so surprising that vote-reweighted
methods, in general, do worse than quota-based ones. Consider the
following situation:
20: Left > Center > Right
20: Right > Center > Left
1: Center > Left = Right
Condorcet would pick Center in the single-winner case. In the situation
of an assembly of two, the reasonable choice (which CPO-STV picks) would
be Left and Right.
However, vote-reweighted methods based on Condorcet would have to start
off by picking Center, since all voters start off with equal weights.
After it has done so, there is not enough room on the assembly to permit
an even division of Left and Right, and thus either Left or Right will
be favored, assuming Center supports both sides equally.
Vote-reweighted methods that aren't based on Condorcet may pick Left and
Right, but they can only do so if they would pick either Left or Right
in the single-winner case.
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list