[Election-Methods] Determining representativeness of multiwinner methods
Diego Santos
diego.renato at gmail.com
Sun Jun 22 19:59:36 PDT 2008
Hi, Kristofer, your idea seems interesting, but I couldn't understand some
points:
- When you presents simulation results, is the best method the one with
greatest or smallest score? IRV is considered the best majoritarian method
but its score is between Nauru-Borda and Plurality
- In some countries, particularly federative ones, many issues are highly
correlated to subnational territories. Because of this, in real scenarios
majoritarian methods are a bit more proportional than in simulations where
all political factions are equally spread within all the country. Had you
considered some correlation with distribution of issue vectors and electoral
districts?
Diego Santos
2008/6/20 Kristofer Munsterhjelm <km-elmet at broadpark.no>:
> Hello all,
>
> (says the newcomer.)
>
> I think I have found a metric for comparing multiwinner systems, at least
> as these pertain to proportional representation, when all votes are honest.
>
> The advantage of the metric is that, if what it measures is desirable, it
> gives an idea of how good the system performs - how representative it is -
> and thus its best case performance. In contrast, criterion failure shows how
> bad a system can get in the worst case.
>
> The broad idea is this: The most proportional assembly is the one which
> reflects the population on all issues. In other words, if a fraction p of
> the population is of a certain position on a binary opinion, it is better
> (ceteris paribus) for a council to have, of that opinion, a fraction close
> to p than one far away from it.
>
> Thus we could make a simulation. First, set that there are n binary issues.
> Each of the voters then have an issue profile which consists of n booleans.
> Set these randomly with different biases for each issue (so that, for
> instance, on the first issue, 70% may hold the "true" position, while on
> another, only 23% do).
>
> Counting the proportion that hold the true-position for each issue gives
> the popular issue profile. In general, the issue profile of a certain subset
> takes the form of n numbers (for n issues), where each number is equal to
> the proportion that holds the true-position for the issue in question.
>
> Then a perfectly representative assembly has an issue profile that is equal
> to the issue profile of the people. So now we have a measure of how well the
> assembly or council represents the people: the more its issue profile
> differs from that of the people, the less representative it is.
>
> However, this presents a problem. How does one aggregate the difference on
> each issue into a single score? Is a one-percent difference on a single
> issue better than 1/n percent difference on all issues? One way to solve
> this is to just settle on an aggregation measure (like root-mean-square) and
> hope the results can be generalized across; another is to use
> Pareto-domination as a measure instead, in saying that councils produced by
> a method A is better than councils produced by a method B to the extent that
> A-councils lie strictly closer to the population profile than does B. That
> approach can give no information on the cases where some issues are closer
> by method A and some are closer by B (mutual nondomination).
>
> Putting all of the pieces together, to figure out the scores, a simulation
> would do something like this:
> - Generate issue vectors for all of the people, and get the
> popular issue profile.
> - Choose a subset of the people as candidates.
> - Generate ballots for each voter of all the candidates.
> - For a great number of random assemblies:
> - Get the issue profile of this assembly, and calculate
> the similarity measure for that with regards to
> the popular issue profile.
> - If the similarity measure is more similar or less
> similar than any random assembly we've seen so
> far, update the worst (respectively best)
> record.
>
> - For each multiwinner election system:
> - Feed the ballots into the system.
> - Get the issue profile of the elected assembly, and
> calculate the similarity measure for that with
> regards to the popular issue profile.
> - Normalize the similarity measure with regards to the
> worst and best random councils.
> - Add the normalized similarity measure to that system's
> running total.
>
> To be robust, it would do this a lot of times with various population
> sizes, council sizes, and issue numbers (n). With a similarity measure, 0
> would be perfect (impossible most of the time), and 1 (or infinity,
> depending on the measure) be the worst possible.
>
> The only thing remaining is to find out how to generate ballots for each
> voter. A reasonable assumption is that voters are going to prefer the
> candidates who agree with them on many issues to those that agree with them
> on a few. For binary issues, Hamming distance works: in the simple model,
> voters rank (or rate) the candidates inversely of Hamming distance.
>
> --
>
> I have made a program that does this. It is simple, does not use equal
> ranks (randomizing preferences instead), but the results are interesting.
>
> Worst of the lot are the majoritarian systems ported to multiwinner
> systems. Those would, for a council of size k, just pick the k first in the
> social order of the single-winner method. This result shouldn't be
> surprising, because the straight port excludes minority opinion. Of some
> curiosity, however, is that IRV does the best among those; maybe it reflects
> IRV's origins as the multiwinner method STV? Or maybe noise (as resulting
> from nonmonotonicity and the likes) bring it closer to the results gained by
> just picking a random assembly.
>
> Then come the vote-reweighted methods, like RRV. Vote-reweighted methods
> can be generalized as: run a single-winner method, then reweight those who
> voted for the winner, according to some function that does not take the
> number of seats into account. Then run again, and disregarding those that
> have already been elected, pick the next member as the one who is closest to
> the top in the social ordering output.
>
> Best of all were the "proper" methods implemented: STV (with Senatorial
> rules) and QLTD-PR, which uses Woodall's QLTD instead of IRV as its basis:
> it adds fractional votes until someone gets above the quota, then reweights
> the voters who contributed to that one, basing the weighting on the
> candidate's surplus.
>
> According to the RMSE scores:
> Majoritarian assemblies:
> Borda: 0.871528 *Plurality: 0.256192
> Antiplurality: 0.73616 Nauru-Borda: 0.599807
> IRV: 0.362097 Cardinal ratings: 0.894351
>
> Vote-reweighted assemblies:
> Borda: 0.376745 *Plurality: 0.260454
> Antiplurality: 0.401539 Nauru-Borda: 0.406815
> RRV (k = 1.0): 0.682116 RRV (k = 0.5): 0.644339
>
> Quota:
> *STV: 0.193959 *QLTD-PR: 0.121693
> QLTD-PR (rated): 0.417813
>
> Other:
> Random Cands: 0.364437
>
> STV-QLTD Pareto dominance: QLTD: 236, STV: 237, nondomin: 674
>
> "Plurality" is the weighted positional system of {1, 0, 0....}
> applied to ranked ballots.
>
> (* marks those that are better than a random assembly, on
> average)
>
> Some of the results may be due to artifacts in the voting pattern - the
> simulator was a proof of concept, after all. I think that Plurality benefits
> by that everyone votes sincerely, and that the ballots are complete, for
> instance. Yet patterns emerge.
>
> If anyone wants to experiment with the simulation program, it is here:
> http://munsterhjelm.no/km/raw/pr_elect.zip . QLTD is called "Quota
> Bucklin" there, as I sort of independently discovered it while trying to
> make a quota-proportional form of Bucklin.
>
> --
>
> On a second thought, it shouldn't be so surprising that vote-reweighted
> methods, in general, do worse than quota-based ones. Consider the following
> situation:
>
> 20: Left > Center > Right
> 20: Right > Center > Left
> 1: Center > Left = Right
>
> Condorcet would pick Center in the single-winner case. In the situation of
> an assembly of two, the reasonable choice (which CPO-STV picks) would be
> Left and Right.
>
> However, vote-reweighted methods based on Condorcet would have to start off
> by picking Center, since all voters start off with equal weights. After it
> has done so, there is not enough room on the assembly to permit an even
> division of Left and Right, and thus either Left or Right will be favored,
> assuming Center supports both sides equally.
>
> Vote-reweighted methods that aren't based on Condorcet may pick Left and
> Right, but they can only do so if they would pick either Left or Right in
> the single-winner case.
> ----
> Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info
>
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20080622/1eb1cd83/attachment.htm>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list