[EM] DH3 pathology, margins, and winning votes
Chris Benham
chrisjbenham at optusnet.com.au
Mon Aug 28 12:20:42 PDT 2006
Warren,
There are some desirable election method properties I insist on in part
because they are so "cheap".
Two of these are Douglas Woodall's "mono-add-plump" and "mono-append".
The first says that if x wins and we add some ballots that plump (bullet
vote) for x, then x must still win.
The second says that if x wins, and then on some ballots that didn't
rank x we rank x immediately below
the previously lowest ranked (above equal-bottom) candidate; x must
still win.
Woodall demonstrates that Smith//IRV, unlike Smith,IRV fails both these
criteria.
(He calls the latter "CNTT,AV" standing for "Condorcet(Net)Top
Tier,Alternative Vote.")
>abcd 10
>bcda 6
>c 2
>dcab 5
>
>All the candidates are in the top tier, and the AV winner is a. But
>if you add two extra ballots that plump for a, or append a to the two
>c ballots, then the CNTT becomes {a,b,c}, and if you delete d from all
>the ballots before applying AV then c wins.
>
So what is a good argument "in the other direction"?
>But I guess this is an argument "for" BTR-IRV;
>
I strongly suspect that BTR-IRV also fails these criteria, and I know
that unlike Smith(Schwartz),IRV
it fails Clone Independence.
From an August 2004 message I sent to the instantrunoff-freewheeling
Yahoo group:
> CB: Standard IRV has some good properties, some of which I regard as
> essential. One of these is Independence of Clones.
> Douglas Woodall splits this into two.
> "Clone-Winner: cloning a candidate who has a positive probability of
> election should not help any other candidate."
> "Clone-Loser: cloning a candidate who has a zero probability of
> election should not change the result of the election."
> (To "clone" candidate x is to add one or more extra candidates,
> which are all ranked adjacently with x and each other by all
> the voters.)
>
> Take this example:
> 25:Brown>Jones>Davis>Smith
> 26:Davis>Smith>Brown>Jones
> 49:Jones>Smith>Brown>Davis
>
> First-preference totals: Jones49, Davis26, Brown25, Smith0.
> "LeGrand IRV"/Bottom-2 Runoffs (BTR) proceeds thus.
> Smith pairwise beats Brown, so Brown is eliminated. (Jones now has an
> unassailable 76 top-preferences).
> Davis > Smith, so Smith is eliminated. Then Jones > Davis, so Jones
> wins.
>
> Now lets clone Davis:
> 25:Brown>Jones>Davis1>Davis2>Smith
> 24:Davis1>Davis2>Smith>Brown>Jones
> 02:Davis2>Davis1>Smith>Brown>Jones
> 49:Jones>Smith>Brown>Davis2>Davis1
>
> First-preference totals: Jones49, Brown25, Davis(1) 24, Davis(2) 2,
> Smith 0.
> Davis2 > Smith, so Smith is eliminated
> Davis2 > Davis1, so Davis1 is eliminated. Top-prefernce totals are
> now: Jones49, Davis(2) 26, Brown25.
> Brown > Davis2, so Davis2 is eliminated.
> Then Brown > Jones, so Brown wins.
>
> Cloning the loser Davis changed the result, so "LeGrand IRV"/BTR
> fails Clone-Loser.
As I understand it, BTR-IRV was invented by Rob Le Grand purely as a
gimmick to try to sell Condorcet
to IRV supporters. I don't think he ever seriously suggested it was
good, and I don't know how anyone
else got that idea.
Chris Benham
Warren Smith wrote:
>I'm not sure your IRV restricted to Smith set BUT do NOT eliminate the
>non-Smith candidates, is better than the pre-elimination.
>
>Think you could make arguments either direction.
>But I guess this is an argument "for" BTR-IRV; with BTR-IRV you do
>not have to worry about that issue, since you get the same result either way.
>
>wds
>----
>election-methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info
>
>
>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list