[EM] Does MAM use the Copeland method?
Paul Kislanko
kislanko at airmail.net
Wed Oct 6 10:26:59 PDT 2004
This is what is intuitively distatefull to us non-specialists about these
methods.
Why should the 33 percent of the voting population who most dislike "A" be
the cause of A to win, whereas 56 pecent rank C>A ?
> -----Original Message-----
> From: election-methods-electorama.com-bounces at electorama.com
> [mailto:election-methods-electorama.com-bounces at electorama.com
> ] On Behalf Of Steve Eppley
> Sent: Wednesday, October 06, 2004 12:05 PM
> To: election-methods at electorama.com
> Subject: Re: [EM] Does MAM use the Copeland method?
>
> Hi,
> Gervase L asked:
> > Just a quick question that should clear up my understanding
> of MAM.
> > Is it the same as Copeland (i.e. count each candidate's number of
> > wins) except that any pairwise wins that are inconsistent with the
> > Rank Pairs ranking are dropped before the Copeland score is tallied
> > up?
>
> No, that's not MAM.
>
> The question itself isn't very clear, since some people use
> the name Ranked Pairs as a synonym for MAM, while others,
> including me, use the name Ranked Pairs to refer only to
> Tideman's 1987 method and Zavist-Tideman's 1989 method.
> Those two methods differ from MAM in several ways, the most
> important difference being that MAM measures the size of each
> majority primarily by the number of votes that rank the
> majority's more-preferred candidate over their less-preferred
> candidate, whereas Tideman and Zavist-Tideman subtract from
> that the size of the opposing minority (that is, the number
> of votes that rank the majority's less-preferred candidate
> over their more-preferred candidate). Because of this, MAM
> satisfies some criteria that Ranked Pairs does not.
>
> MAM constructs the order of finish of the candidates a piece
> at a time, by considering the majorities one at a time from
> largest to smallest, adopting into the finish order each
> majority's preference that does not conflict
> (cycle) with the partial order of finish already constructed.
> The winner is the candidate that tops the order of finish so
> constructed. (In a multiwinner context, the N winners are the
> N candidates that top the order of finish.)
>
> Here's a simple example to illustrate:
>
> 9 voters, 3 candidates
>
> The votes:
> 4: A>B>C
> 3: B>C>A
> 2: C>A>B
>
> There are three majorities:
> 7: B>C
> 6: A>B
> 5: C>A
>
> MAM first adopts the preference of the largest majority,
> for B over C. Thus B finishes over C. Then MAM adopts
> the preference of the second largest majority, for
> A over B. Thus A finishes over B. Since MAM is
> constructing an ordering and A finishes over B and
> B finishes over C, this implies A finishes over C.
> So when MAM considers the preference of the third
> largest majority, for C over A, it is not adopted
> since it has already been established that A finishes
> over C. Thus the complete order of finish is A>B>C.
> Since A tops the finish order, A is elected.
>
> I've oversimplified a bit. When the number of voters is
> small, it's not implausible that two or more majorities will
> be the same size and it's not implausible that one or more
> pairings won't have a majority (in other words, a pairing may
> be a "tie.") For more details about MAM, see my web pages at
> <www.alumni.caltech.edu/~seppley>.
>
> --Steve
>
> ----
> Election-methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em
> for list info
>
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list