[EM] 09/20/02 - The Manipulation Test:
Adam Tarr
atarr at purdue.edu
Fri Sep 20 16:17:52 PDT 2002
Donald Davison wrote:
>Mike Saari: "Suppose there are only two candidates, or suppose that all
>candidates have been eliminated down to only two.
>
>Here is the sample scenario:
>All of the voters rate candidate "B" as "very good".
>60% of the voters rate candidate "A" as "excellent"
>The other 40% of the voters rate candidate "A" as "awful".
>
>Donald: Candidate A is the winner. I'm telling you that right up front. I
>don't need to hear a bunch of twisted logic to the contrary.
Don, you're pretty much right. What's more, you're right regardless of the
voting system. I mean, we're talking about two candidates here. It's not
complicated. Regardless of what the voting system is, you just vote for
the candidate you like more. This applies to approval voting too. I mean
really, do you expect that an "A" supporter would walk into the voting
booth and vote for BOTH available candidates? They may as well just stay
home and watch Baywatch reruns.
Even if Mike Saari gravitates toward approval voting, his proposed election
gives the same result with approval voting as it does with any other
deterministic voting method.
>Mike Saari: "So which candidate is the "better" choice - the one liked by
>everybody, or the one hated by 40% of the group?"
>
>Donald: Answer: Candidate `A'. See I told you you're not going to get
>from me the answer you are looking for.
Here I disagree with you. In a perfect world, "B" wins the election, and
everyone is fairly content. But we don't live in a perfect world. The "A"
supporters have a majority, so they get what they want, even though they
are aware that they could live with "B". This is true no matter what
voting system we choose.
Now, I can come up with a couple situations where approval voting, and its
sibling cardinal rankings, will elect a "B"-type candidate over an "A"-type
candidate. But these situations will have two things in common:
1) The voters don't know the numbers of the current polls with any accuracy.
2) There is a third, disliked option that scares the A voters into voting
for B.
For example, let's say in stead of 60% "A" and 40% "B", we have 45% "A" 30%
"B", and 25% "C". The A and B voters all hate C, and the C voters have no
preference between A and B.
In plurality, IRV, or Condorcet, A still wins the election. This is also
true in approval voting or cardinal rankings if the voters know the poll
numbers. But if the "A" voters are in the dark about the poll numbers,
they may approve B as well to protect from C. If that happens, then B wins
the election.
>Mike Saari: "Such a belief is unfounded, though, if you realize that this
>method creates a "40% are unhappy" group, whereas a system with some
>possibility to choose the less "exciting" (but liked by all) candidate B
>creates a group which is more contented overall."
Short of plugging every voter into a polygraph and interrogating them, we
have no way to figure out exactly how much more the voter likes one
candidate as compared to the next. Expecting voters to act against self
interest because it maximizes overall social utility is a losing battle.
>Donald: If this is the best argument you can present for Approval Voting,
>then you lose, because almost everyone wants their own number one to win.
>The Approval supporters are fools to think Nader would have won if the last
>Presidential election was an Approval Voting election.
I don't think anybody seriously thinks that. Is that last line anything
but a pot shot at greens who support approval voting?
Anyway, this is not the best argument for approval voting in my book,
although it is a subset of one decent argument for approval - that voters
can produce very good results even if the media covering the election gives
unreliable information.
-Adam
----
For more information about this list (subscribe, unsubscribe, FAQ, etc),
please see http://www.eskimo.com/~robla/em
More information about the Election-Methods
mailing list